The politics of renewable energy policy: why do (not) the Russian regions implement the mechanism of renewable energy support
Feature description of the renewable energy federalism. Familiarization with the principles of Putin’s era. Study of Russia's price zones of the wholesale electricity market. Review and analysis of the annual capacity limits versus tender results.
Рубрика | Политология |
Вид | диссертация |
Язык | английский |
Дата добавления | 16.07.2020 |
Размер файла | 1,6 M |
Отправить свою хорошую работу в базу знаний просто. Используйте форму, расположенную ниже
Студенты, аспиранты, молодые ученые, использующие базу знаний в своей учебе и работе, будут вам очень благодарны.
Размещено на http://www.allbest.ru/
NATIONAL RESEARCH UNIVERSITY
HIGHER SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS
HSE Saint-Petersburg School of Social Sciences and Area Studies
Thesis
The politics of renewable energy policy: why do (not) the Russian regions implement the mechanism of renewable energy support
In the field of study 41.03.04 `Political Science'
Reviewer Academic supervisor PhD in Political Science A.A. Dekaltchouk
Student of Group No. 161 (`Political Science and World Politics' degree programme) Ruslan Valiev
Saint Petersburg 2020
Annotation
В рамках данного исследования мы выяснили, какие политические факторы повлияли на решение регионов Российской Федерации в пользу (не) реализации механизма поддержки возобновляемых источников энергии (ВИЭ) на основе договоров поставки мощностей (ДПМ) с 2013 по 2018 год. С помощью логистической и Пуассоновской регрессий, было выявлено, что это приближающиеся выборы в регионе, уровень связи региона с федеральным центром, а также тот факт, что регион имеет богатые запасы углеводородных полезных ископаемых.
This paper focuses on the capacity based renewable energy support scheme (CRESS) analysis in Russian regions. The purpose is to reveal the reasons why in some regions the CRESS was implemented, while in the others it was not. Statistical methods of analysis will be used to figure out the political factors that could affect its implementation from 2013 to 2018 in each region. Among them there could be distinguished: upcoming elections, the fossil resources endowment, the openness of the political regime, and the level of regions' connection with the federal center. As a result, we have upcoming elections, the fossil resources endowment, and the level of regions' connection with the federal center factors to influence the regions' decision (not) to implement the CRESS.
Content
- Annotation
- Introduction
- 1. Capacity-based renewable energy support scheme in Russia
- 1.1 Russia's federal system
- 1.1.1 Origins: 1990
- 1.1.2 Putin's era: 2000s-2010
- 1.2 Renewable energy in Russia's federal system
- 1.3 The policy process: Russia's capacity-based renewable energy support scheme
- 1.3.1 The agenda setting stage
- 1.3.2 The policy formulation stage
- 1.3.3 The policy implementation stage
- 2. What factors can influence energy policy
- 2.1 Renewable energy federalism
- 2.2 What are enabling and constraining factors for implementation
- 2.2.1 Governors' and legislatures' upcoming elections
- 2.2.2 Lock-in effect
- 2.2.3 Vested interests as a driving factor
- 2.2.4 Connection to the federal level
- 2.2.5 Effective number of parties
- 2.2.6 Technology and Innovation patents
- 2.2.7 Electricity market factors
- 2.2.8 Socioeconomic factors
- 2.3 Setting of hypotheses
- 3. The regression analysis of political factors
- 3.1 Poisson and logistic regression analyses
- 3.2 Data collection and sources
- 3.3 Logistic regression results
- 3.4 Poisson regression results
- 3.5 Interpretation of results
- Conclusion
- Bibliography
Introduction
Usually, Russia is automatically excluded from the global debate with regard to `renewable energy'. Mitrova, Tatiana, and Yuriy Melnikov. 2019. "Energy Transition In Russia". Energy Transitions, 3. It can obviously be explained by the fact that the Russian Federation is one of the biggest producers and exporters of fossil fuels worldwide. Thereby, this by default presupposes that the state is not a subject of the world-wide sustainable development processes, but strictly the opposite - it is not interested in it. A plethora of renewable energy (RE) politics scholars and the very research, though, proclaim that this is not completely true. Smeets, Niels. 2017. "Similar Goals, Divergent Motives. The Enabling And Constraining Factors Of Russia's Capacity-Based Renewable Energy Support Scheme". Energy Policy 101: 140.; McConnell, Dylan, and Patrick Hearps. 2011. "Renewable Energy Technology Cost Review". Technical Paper Series, 60.
Despite the common narrative, the Russian government sets the production of electricity based on renewable energy resources (solar, wind, and small hydro) as, at least in principle, “a political priority of the Russian energy policy”. Russian Government. 2008. "Conception For The Long-Term Social And Economic Development Of The Russian Federation Until 2020". Moscow (as amended by Resolution of the Russian Government No. 1151 of 28 September 2018).; Russian Government. 2009. "Resolution On Main Directions Of The State Policy To Increase The Energy Efficiency Of The Electricity Sector Based On The Use Of Renewable Energy Sources". Moscow.; Russian Government. 2013. “Decree on the Mechanism to Promote the Use of Renewable Energy Sources in the Wholesale Electricity Market”. Moscow.; Russian Government. 2018. “Resolution on the Introduction of Changes to Certain Acts of the Russian Government No. 1151”. Moscow.; President, Russian. 2019. “Order on the Approval of the Energy Security Doctrine of Russia”. Moscow. Since November 2007 the federal electricity law No. 35-FZ Federal'nyi Zakon “Ob eletkroenergetike” with subsequent amendments (26 March 2003) No.35-FZ, SZRF (2003) No.13 item 1177. mandates “the federal government to promote the development of renewable energy sources” within regional units. Boute, Anatole, and Alexey Zhikharev. 2019. "Vested Interests As Driver Of The Clean Energy Transition: Evidence From Russia's Solar Energy Policy". Energy Policy 133: 1. One year later, the federal authorities and even the President started highlighting the importance of green resources and energy transition in their reports almost annually. President, Russian. 2016. “Order on the Approval of the Strategy for the Scientific and Technological Development of Russia”. Moscow.; President, Russian. 2019. “Order on the Approval of the Energy Security Doctrine of Russia”. Moscow. In this context, as Boute and Zhikharev notice, the Russian government is surprisingly ambitious to become a world leader in the development of green energy technologies. Boute, Anatole, and Alexey Zhikharev. 2019. Op. Cit. 1.
Such new political trajectory of both the Russian government and the President resulted in a premium scheme of RE support in 2008. The key feature of it was to reward green energy producers for an amount of produced energy in MWh. The history of the scheme was comparatively short, and it was yet replaced by a new policy instrument in 2013 due to the political contestation of the new-formed sphere of energy production. Ibid.
The new policy instrument was named as a capacity-based renewable energy support scheme (CRESS). The main goal of CRESS is to attract investments into the regions' electricity production setting the regional level as the main ground of RE promotion. Ibid. The new federal policy instrument entered the implementation stage in the very 2013 which consequently brought some results. Some regions like Bashkortostan Republic, Orenburg oblast', and others which have renewable energy geographical potential have used the scheme and helped companies to set several projects on their territories. At the same time, some regions with similar potentials like Dagestan, Ingushetia etc. have not done this. The logical question here is - why?
We can also elaborate the arisen question by adding Busigina's notice about the nature of Russia during the end of 2000s and the beginning of 2010s. The scholar says that Russia during this period is mostly described by a strong power vertical (centralized power) between the federal center and the regions which has been created by Putin since he came to power in 2000. Boute, Anatole, and Alexey Zhikharev. 2019. Op. Cit. 1. However, it might be questioned if we try to think why the very federal-based initiative was and is perceived by sub-federal units differently (in a decentralized manner): why some regions do tend to accept and to implement this CRESS whereas others do not. This collision is yet fueled by the competences regions have towards this scheme because the federal power vertical usually has an inherent to take them away from its federal units. These competences in our case are like a right to participate in auctions by which RE projects are selected for support, a right to give a rent-permission for plots of lands for RE stations etc.
This logical collision also come along with the fact that we cannot fully consider this country as a subject of sustainable energy development processes because we cannot observe any substantial results of the trendy and loud political statements. The production of electricity with the use of green technologies is still less than 1% presently - after almost 12 years of “sustainable development” throughout Russia (despite a comparatively high quantitative goal of 2.5% by 2024). Ibid.; "Renewable Energy Statistics 2017". 2019. Irena.Org. https://www.irena.org/publications/2017/Jul/Renewable-Energy-Statistics-2017. Russia still greatly relies on fossil fuels which logically understandable because they are cheaper and they are easier to extract. That is why the narrative that Russia is not particularly interested in the incorporation of renewable energy sources is, at least empirically, grounded, but not to the full extent.
Why are all these actions to promote RE electricity production taken by the Russian government if we can hardly see any results of them like rates' improvement? Why does the general policy of the central Russian authorities stake on the regional governments in the RE promotion? Why do some regions tend to accept and to implement this CRESS whereas others do not in conditions of the federal power vertical? All this presents the research puzzle of our work.
It is a pity there are as many elaborations on these questions as there are scholars in the field. Therefore, academia has a plenty of versions about what stands behind the ineffective renewable energy transition in Russia.
(Before we can move to discussing these versions, it is important to mention that `renewable (green) energy transition' is a major switch in a state from the use of traditional fossil fuels like gas and oil in electricity generation to energy sources which are less or not harmful for the environment (solar and wind power etc.). Leach, Gerald. 1992. "The Energy Transition". Energy Policy 20 (2): 116-123.; Pegels, Anna, and Wilfried LLtkenhorst. 2014. "Is Germany's Energy Transition A Case Of Successful Green Industrial Policy? Contrasting Wind And Solar PV". SSRN Electronic Journal, 1-33.)
The first and the most popular explanation in the renewable energy transition research traditionally comes from the economic and financial spheres. Smeets, building on the expertise of Hearps and McConnell, takes the perspective that the Russian central government (along with the regional authorities) is trying to introduce green electricity generation to “minimize capital costs”. Smeets, Niels. 2017. Op. Cit. 101: 140.; McConnell, Dylan, and Patrick Hearps. 2011. Op. Cit. 60. Undoubtedly, this can be so, however, these arguments do not explain the fact that in most regions the tariffs for the RE electricity are appreciably higher than the costs of their conventional alternatives like gas or diesel. That is why a different explanation might be needed.
Another possible answer arises from the institutionalist perspective. Gel'man's argument about the neopatrimonial nature of Russian policy making where the “executive power and oligarchic business actors greatly affect it [policy making]” seems to be relevant here. Gel'man, Vladimir. 2015. "The Vicious Circle Of Post-Soviet Neopatrimonialism In Russia". Post-Soviet Affairs 32 (5): 455-473.; Petrov, Nikolay, Maria Lipman, and Henry E. Hale. 2013. "Three Dilemmas Of Hybrid Regime Governance: Russia From Putin To Putin". Post-Soviet Affairs 30 (1): 1-26. In other words, RE sphere in Russia is ineffective because business and politics are linked together. Such a political project might be slowed down by fossil fuels business's resistance. Notwithstanding, there is a rebuttal of such arguments claiming that the elites' role has a twofold nature which eliminates this `top-down' argument about the incentives of Russia and its regions. Boute, Anatole, and Alexey Zhikharev. 2019. Op. Cit. 1. A twofold nature means that such oligarchs and politicians who logically should resist RE development - paradoxically support it.
The third perspective which helps explain why the green energy sphere has been promoted in Russia can be called regionalist. As it has been already mentioned, from the very beginning the newly pronounced green energy policy in 2013 has had a strong regional dimension. With the launch of the policy the federal power in Russia gave the regional authorities a wide spectrum of regulatory powers for further RE incorporation. Boute, Anatole. 2013. "Renewable Energy Federalism In Russia: Regions As New Actors For The Promotion Of Clean Energy". Journal Of Environmental Law 25 (2): 265. Boute argues that this decision had two consequences. On the one hand, the federal level was supposed “to stimulate local employment, innovation and secure electricity supply, particularly for regions that are dependent on energy imports” by transferring these powers to the regional level. Ibid. On the other, many of the regions were faced with the paralysis or with the crucial regulatory and political obstacles. Ibid. The paralysis was and is in a clash between what regions are expected to do from the federal center (their loyalty, for instance) and what they are capable of doing with these competences which they are not usually accustomed to having. Following Boute's logic, these have become the major causes of the failed implementation of the renewable energy policy in Russia.
Building on this latter perspective, we believe the question of the regional incentives (rather than federal-level incentives) to be the departure point for any research into the reasons for the adoption of renewable energy in Russia. Such reasons are under-researched from the point of view of political science. What is more, such perspective also brings us to an interesting theoretical debates of how political subnational units' decision-making mechanism works. Engel, Kirsten H. 2015. "EPA's Clean Power Plan: An Emerging New Cooperative Federalism?". SSRN Electronic Journal, 79-105.; Sovacool, Benjamin K. 2008. "A Matter Of Stability And Equity: The Case For Federal Action On Renewable Portfolio Standards In The U.S.". Energy & Environment 19 (2): 241-261. That is why we will try to look at political reasons of the adoption of RE in Russian regions.
Thereby, the research question of our paper can be formulated as follows. What are the political factors, which made the Russian regions (not) implement the capacity-based renewable energy support scheme in between 2013 and 2018?
To justify the wording of the research question we should specify some aspects. The first point of justification desires a special attention - political factors. We follow Vasseur's argument that a policy of a regional adoption of RE is patterned from a combination of region-level political interests and policy-making institutions. Vasseur, Michael. 2016. "Incentives Or Mandates? Determinants Of The Renewable Energy Policies Of U.S. States, 1970-2012". Social Problems 63 (2): 287-290. Interests-based factors encompass political actors' interests, including both politicians and outside actors like businesses. Institutional ones “show that the structure of formal policy-making institutions influences policy adoption”. Ibid. In other words, our paper will use the theoretical language of new institutionalism because we consider not only institutions' influence, but also an interplay of actors' interests and institutions.
Based on the chosen axis of political factors, there are some possible suggestions which we believe could influence regions' decision-making process (not) to implement the support scheme. Thus, one of the possible answers can be found in Nordhause's political electoral cycles theory. Such cycles push politicians in the end of their political term make a stake on low-risk populistic policies with no long-term perspectives to gain their electorate support as quick as possible to win an upcoming elections. Nordhaus, William D. 1975. "The Political Business Cycle". The Review Of Economic Studies 42 (2): 169.; Akhmedov A.M. Chelovecheskiy Kapital i Politicheskiye Biznes-tsikly // Akhmedov, A. 2006. "Chelovecheskiy Kapital I Politicheskiye Biznes-Tsikly". Konsortsium Ekonomicheskikh Issledovanii€ I Obrazovaniya, Rossiya I SNG, no. 6: 7. It means that in regions where an elections is upcoming, the chances that an RE support policy will go through are lower because it is mostly unpopular. Another possible factor which literature suggests is called the `lock-in' effect. The oft-cited effect of institutional `stickiness' appears “when there are complex and large-scale socio-technological systems which remain dominant by creating strong resistance against introducing new technologies”. Goldthau, Andreas, and Benjamin K. Sovacool. 2012. "The Uniqueness Of The Energy Security, Justice, And Governance Problem". Energy Policy 41: 232-240. This factor can be integrated in our research in a way that there are some export-oriented regions in Russia which function and develop only through gas and oil revenues. It shows that they would hardly agree to implement CRESS due to `lock-in' effect, but the import-oriented regions which are not energy-endowed and, consequently, are not locked-in would have more incentives to implement the support policy. All other hypothesized determinants in a way of independent variables will be described in the third chapter of our paper.
As for the second point of the justification of our research question, if we want to highlight valuable indicators to truly understand political reasons of why regional entities make or do not make a choice in favor of the CRESS adoption and implementation, we have to look not only at those which have actually started the adoption, but at the rest of non-users as well. We are not going to take all the Russian regions because the Russian Ministry of Energy sets that the CREESS mechanism is available only for those regions which belong to the first and second electricity price zones. These are regions from European Russia and Western Siberia. The overall number of regions which we can use for an analysis is 58 out of 85. We will elaborate this point of selection in detail in the third chapter of our paper. The third point is about the chosen time period which is defined by the two factors. The first one arises contextually because in 2013 the first renewables projects were set up. The second is mostly about data availability.
Thus, this research aims to establish political factors, which make the Russian regions (not) implement the capacity-based renewable energy support scheme in between 2013 and 2018. Each possible reason will enter our research in the form of a hypothesis in the literature review section, which will be further tested in the empirical part of the work.
The empirical framework of the work addresses an implementation of the renewable energy support policy in the Russian regions. Theoretically, we are going to study political factors which can possibly influence regional units (not) to implement renewable energy support mechanisms.
A methodological approach will be a classical statistical research with the use of regression analysis. The choice is justified by the number of cases - 58 regions. We will take a look at the 58 different implementations of the CRESS policy for the last 6 years: from 2013 to 2018.
The method of the research will not be uniform. In contrast, we are going to use a statistical regression analysis of two types: logistic and Poisson regression analyses. Both of them allow us to identify a likelihood that a dependent variable of our research is going to happen when there is presence or absence of a bulk of political factors. We choose the logistic regression due to a possibility of transforming our dependent variable into a binary form: we can mark as 1 if the CRESS is actually implemented in a region in a year and mark as 0 if it is not. The Poisson regression analysis is chosen by us to overcome a possible bad dispersion of our data in the logistic regression caused by rare frequency of the CRESS projects for 6 years. The Poisson regression analysis is applied by scholars in the very situations when the frequency of an event is low and when a dependent variable can be transformed into the countable form (in the form of continuous integers). That is why we will purposely use the second dependent variable for the Poisson regression - an increase (delta) in a number of RE projects in a region in contrast to a previous year. As for the data collection, we will rely on the open databases of the federal Russian agencies, which are deeply described in the third chapter.
The thesis is structured as follows. In the first chapter, we will review the literature on a regional implementation of renewable energy support policies and will formulate hypotheses. In the second chapter, we will describe the policy of the capacity-based renewable energy support scheme in the Russian regions basing the structure of the description on the existing scholarly research in the field. The last third chapter is left for the regression analysis and the interpretation of the results.
1. Capacity-based renewable energy support scheme in Russia
This chapter is going to concentrate on the very renewable energy policy process in Russia called the capacity-based renewable energy support scheme (CRESS), to wit, on its implementation. We will review the relevant empirical literature on the scheme in a way Smeeth does it in his research: he describes the CRESS by dividing it into theory-based policy process stages by accompanying each of them with a proper literature. Thus, we will determine in greater detail the CRESS initiative in Russia and will characterize circumstances which it was engineered and implemented in. However, before we will move to this step, it is essential to clarify how the federal system in Russia works, what the constitutional division between layers of power is, and whether the regions in Russia have sufficient regulatory power to influence renewables' promotion at all. Such small prologue is necessary for a better understanding of what the CRESS is. All these little steps will create a necessary ground for the next theoretical chapter of our research.
1.1 Russia's federal system
In Russia, the Constitution “establishes the federal nature of Russia's state system”. Boute, Anatole. 2013. Op. Cit., 11. Currently, the Russian Federation consists of 85 federal subjects which are clustered into 5 types: 22 republics, 9 krais, 46 oblasts, 3 federal cities, 1 autonomous oblast, and 4 autonomous okrugs. "Chapter 3. The Federal Structure. Art 65. The Constitution Of The Russian Federation". 2020. Constitution.Ru. http://www.constitution.ru/en/10003000-04.htm. All of them are constituent members of the federation, which automatically means they exercise state authority within the constitutional power-separation between federal and regional levels of government. Boute, Anatole. 2013. Op. Cit., 11. In other words, the Russian regions constitutionally have the right to regulate any issue that is not preliminary within the federal center's responsibility or within both “the federal and the regional authorities' responsibility (the so-called `shared competences')”. Ibid. The example of the exclusive federal competence is Article 71 of the Russian Constitution, wherein “the federal authorities have the exclusive competence to regulate the federal energy systems and nuclear energy”. Ibid.; "Chapter 3. The Federal Structure. Art 65-79. | The Constitution Of The Russian Federation". 2020. Constitution.Ru. http://www.constitution.ru/en/10003000-04.htm. In continuation, the shared competences have their own limits for the sub-federal level. It means that the regions can regulate a shared issue up until the federal center makes a decision to intervene or, as Boute puts it, to `pre-empt'. Boute, Anatole. 2013. Op. Cit., 12. For instance, Article 72 of the Russian Constitution establishes “shared federal-regional competences for the regulation of environmental protection and environmental security”. Ibid. "Chapter 3. The Federal Structure. Art 65-79. | The Constitution Of The Russian Federation". 2020. Constitution.Ru. http://www.constitution.ru/en/10003000-04.htm.
Overall, the established nature of the relationship between the federal center and regional units has the clear notion of `power vertical' between the authorities' layers where the lower serves the upper. However, besides the described formal superiority when the federal law always prevails with regard to the regional one (even in conflicts), the Russian federal system has several important informal rules of the game which are also covered by the `power vertical' notion. In order to explain this particular notion, we have to look at the origins of the federal system in Russia - in 1990s, and at the present system after that.
1.1.1 Origins: 1990
The federal system of the Russian Federation has changed dramatically since the beginning of the 2000s. Bary, Dona. 2004. "Novyy Federalizm I Paradoksy Regional'nogo Suvereniteta V Rossii". In Federalizm: Rossiyskoye I Mezhdunarodnoye Izmereniya (Opyt Sravnitel'nogo Analiza). Kazan'.; Gel'man, Vladimir, and Sergei Ryzhenkov. 2011. "Local Regimes, Sub-National Governance And The `Power Vertical' In Contemporary Russia". Europe-Asia Studies 63 (3): 451; Gel'man, Vladimir. 2006. "Leviathan's Come-Back? (Policy Of Recentralization In Contemporary Russia)", no. 2: 90-109. The change was connected with the end of the Yeltsin era, to wit, with the end of constitutional and purely informal federal system and the beginning of the highly politicized `negotiated' federal system of the Putin's era. Ross, Cameron. 2010. "Federalism And Inter-Governmental Relations In Russia". Journal Of Communist Studies And Transition Politics 26 (2): 170. In the 1990s the collapse of the Soviet regime and the setting of market reforms triggered the logical decentralization and democratization processes at the regional level. Gel'man, Vladimir, and Sergei Ryzhenkov. 2011. Op. Cit. 450.: Zubarevich, Natalya. 2010. "State-Business Relations In Russia'S Regions", 211-226. The logical decrease in the central capacities of Russia to distribute and coerce power in both political and economic dimensions with regard to sub-federal units caused, as Gel'man alleges, a great diversity in terms of regional politics. Ibid. We can simply call it as the partial devolution of power from the federal government to the regional governments with the orientation of the latter to maintain the “status quo, which was based upon redistributive social policies”. Ibid.
It thus created a new regional system where regions could directly influence the central government, and set their own policies and legislation which were not in favor and did not correspond to those of the federal center. Bary concludes that the federal government, in order to stop the decentralization, was forced to start signing bilateral agreements with the regional governments to share competences granting subnational units some privileges. Bary, Dona. 2004. Op. Cit. The number of regional-based normative acts reached 300,000, but everything was condemned to become upside down due to an upcoming political event.
1.1.2 Putin's era: 2000s-2010
After the new President Putin came to power in 2000, he launched a new political agenda to “reassert the powers of the Kremlin over the regions”. Ross, Cameron. 2010. Op. Cit. It set the new nature of the federal system in Russia which Gel'man and Sharafutdinova call the `power vertical'. Gel'man, Vladimir, and Sergei Ryzhenkov. 2011. Op. Cit.; Sharafutdinova, Gulnaz, and Rostislav Turovsky. 2016. "The Politics Of Federal Transfers In Putin'S Russia: Regional Competition, Lobbying, And Federal Priorities". Post-Soviet Affairs 33 (2): 161-175. This term denotes “a hierarchical model of regional governance” and, furthermore, it costs Russia tremendous political changes. The mechanism of `power vertical', as it has already been said, works through several formal and informal rules of the game.
First, it leads to almost full deactivation of electoral contestation in regional and national politics. Golosov, Grigori. 2008. "Elektoral'Nyi Avtoritarizm V Rossii". Pro Et Contra 12 (1): 22-35. Gel'man and Sharafutdinova claim that, for Russia, such an electoral abolishment meant (and means) “the de-facto prohibition of open political competition of regional elites” with the following integration of them into a new party of power, the United Russia (Edinaya Rossiya) party. Gel'man, Vladimir, and Sergei Ryzhenkov. 2011. Op. Cit.: Golosov, Grigori. 2008. "Elektoral'Nyi Avtoritarizm V Rossii". Pro Et Contra 12 (1): 22-35. Second, the `power vertical' reduces the political independence of regional governors. In the Russian case, when the process of recentralization took place, the Kremlin hierarchically subordinated regional chief executives and city mayors since 2004 by the approval of the upper chamber of the Russian parliament to allow the President to suggest them to be appointed (however, in 2012 the governors' elections were restored). Busygina, Irina. Op. Cit. 105-119.: Ross, Cameron. 2005. "Federalism And Electoral Authoritarianism Under Putin". Demokratizatsiya: The Journal Of Post-Soviet Democratization 13 (3): 347-372. Last, but not least, the vertical model of governance used by a federal center usually requires subnational units to have (1) permanent favorable electoral results and (2) to have a well-functioned anti-protests structures in order not to be dismissed by the center. Gel'man, Vladimir, and Sergei Ryzhenkov. 2011. Op. Cit.; Sharafutdinova, Gulnaz, and Rostislav Turovsky. 2016. Op. Cit. Busygina, along with Gel'man and Ryzhenkov, also highlights that the federal center demands (3) social patronage as the permanent pillar of sub-federal political stability as well. Busygina, Irina. 2016. Op Cit. 113.; Gel'man, Vladimir, and Sergei Ryzhenkov. 2011. Op. Cit.
To sum up intermediate results, the new turn from the much-decentralized Russian federal system with a weak federal center and chaotic regional political structures to the new strict form of centralization with the strong federal center and supervised regions can be described in a twofold manner. On the one hand, some researches proclaim that the new form of vertical governance brings to the regions of Russia an old-fashioned style of “unitary federation” where everything is handled by the center. Ibid. Nevertheless, on the other hand, Busygina argues that the time actually proved the Russian `power vertical' not to working “like the strict hierarchy of a unitary state; it was much more reminiscent of an imperial order”. Busygina, Irina. 2016. Op Cit. 113. It means that instead of a total control, the new system creates a kind of principal-agent order between the two layers: the federal executive (the principal) and the regions (agents).
For instance, Moscow can ask regions to fulfill these demands on an ongoing basis, but then it is mostly indifferent to what it is going on in the regions. The center now has the instrument and intention to punish and reward, but not to instantly control the regions. Ibid. If we can clearly see what stands behind the punishment for the regional elites (to be dismissed by the center), the reward instrument is more vague. Paradoxically, Busygina and Gel'man with Ryzhenkov believe that after the federal demands are fulfilled by the Russian sub-federal units, “Moscow in fact connives with regional executives giving them freedom which represented their reward”. Ibid.; Gel'man, Vladimir, and Sergei Ryzhenkov. 2011. Op. Cit. What is more, the regional power can increase the degree of its freedom by an asymmetrical exchange of an information with the federal center, misinforming it. Ibid. Notwithstanding, such a free space does not bring any incentives for the governors and the regional elites to be creative and, for instance, to make their regions investment- and labor-attractive to compete with each other. Ibid. It is simply because the federal center does not expect it from them and the informal agreement is mainly about “loyalty and electoral results”. Busygina, Irina. 2016. Op Cit. 113. Eventually, it is just too risky to be creative, but it is still possible and that is the most significant conclusion.
Having said so, we can understand that the `power vertical' model of the federal governance in Russia creates not a despotic system as such, but the strict, stable, and center-oriented dual system where the interests of both the upper and lower layers of government can more or less be satisfied by a mutual informal agreement. However, the very essence of the agreement is to limit and to control the regional authorities not by systematic command, but by the described `carrot and stick' policy. The carrot in its turn allows the sub-federal units in Russia to have some freedom which is limited by the center. Nevertheless, there is no doubt that some creative activities (policies) - if they are not about elections, social policies, or strikes - are more than possible in the regions if their political elites are brave enough to take a risk.
At this point, it is crucial to connect the reviewed federal system of the Russian Federation with the renewable energy sphere in the next sub-section before we can move to the key part of the chapter itself - the CRESS.
1.2 Renewable energy in Russia's federal system
First and foremost, main goal of renewable energy is to provide consumers with electricity, logically meaning that RE is a part of the electricity sphere. In Russia, the electricity sector is a prominent example of `power vertical' centralization of power at the federal level. Boute, Anatole. 2013. Op. Cit. 13. The Russian electricity sector is so giant that the Russian government has to control it via a unified (all-Russia) approach (it is called the Unified Energy System (UES) of the RF). Federal'nyy Zakon "Ob Elektroenergetike" Ot 26.03.2003 N 35-FZ. 2003. Art. 4-6. The same logic is traced in the legal regulation of the UES where “the Federal Electricity Law `pre-empts', on the basis of the study made by Boute, regulation in the electricity sector”, Boute, Anatole. 2013. Op. Cit. 12-13.; Federal'nyy Zakon "Ob Elektroenergetike" Ot 26.03.2003 N 35-FZ. 2003. Art. 4. i.e., regional authorities in Russia are not able to freely act in the electricity sector unless they are allowed to do so by the federal center. The afore-mentioned Article 72 of the Constitution also explicitly establishes the federal regulation of renewable energy sources, including the promotion of RE in the Russian regions. "Chapter 3. The Federal Structure. Art 65-79. | The Constitution Of The Russian Federation". 2020. Constitution.Ru. http://www.constitution.ru/en/10003000-04.htm. Hereafter, there is no space for the regional level to act.
The regulation of RE in Russia, to wit, the determination of strategies and measures (and support schemes as well), is put on the shoulders of the federal government as we have already understood. However, to manage such big processes is the task of the special regulator (for the wholesale market) called the Market Council which is responsible for qualification of all RE facilities in the country. Boute, Anatole. 2013. Op. Cit. 12-13. Regions are ironically excluded from these processes too despite the fact that the qualification task (Boute calls it “the cornerstone of the RE system in Russia) directly affects whether a facility in a particular region will be supported by a governmental maintenance (the CRESS) or not.
Nonetheless, even within the federal-biased regulation of renewable and, correspondingly, electricity spheres in Russia, there are some unique regional competences which create the most important means of overcoming the `power vertical' formal obstacles for the Russian regions - the normative ones. With regard to the wholesale market, regions are rewarded by the Government Decrees (GD) numbers 823 and 1225 about the Russian Energy Efficiency Strategy with the legal responsibility to deploy renewables as an energy improvement measure within regional energy efficiency programs including the CRESS.Governmental Decree N823 "O SKHEMAKH I PROGRAMMAKH PERSPEKTIVNOGO RAZVITIYA ELEKTROENERGETIKI". 2009.; Governmental Decree N1225 “O trebovaniyakh k regional'nym i munitsipal'nym programmam v oblasti energosberezheniya i povysheniya energeticheskoy effektivnosti”. 2009. Basically, these GDs confer regional authority with the obligation to participate and to influence federal and regional strategies towards economic benefits from RE sources. Ibid. What does it imply in detail for an understating of what competences regions have with regard to the renewable energy based support scheme?
Specifically for the CRESS, with the reference to the Russian Ministry of Energy, regions are given a right: (1) to issue a land tenure permit for businesses to launch renewable energy based power plants and (2) to define terms and conditions of the inclusion of renewable energy generating facilities in a region's electric development plan. Ibid. We cannot but mention that our research takes as a risk that regional authorities of the Russian federation, on the basis of the above-mentioned competences, are able to influence the CRESS promotion in their regions. The risk is based upon the vagueness of the competences' formulation which are either too broad to use them effectively or which are broad enough to influence the CRESS.
With regard to the retail market, one of the main competences to adapt renewable energy sources of electricity (RES-E) tariffs is granted to the regional authorities. Such tariffs play a central role in regional RE policies, “since they are responsible to determine the price at which network companies purchase RES-E”. Boute, Anatole. 2013. Op. Cit. 15. The GD of the Russian Federation number 97 about the Regulation of the Regional Tariff Authorities allows regional authorities to determine the procedure of the formation of tariffs and their regulation. Governmental Decree N97 “O federal'nykh standartakh oplaty zhilogo pomeshcheniya i kommunal'nykh uslug na 2016 - 2018 gody”. 2016. Another important competence which is given to regions as a reward is to organize a contest among RE companies for a governmental maintenance. Ibid.
Overall, we can see that the formal situation in the sphere of renewable energy sources in Russia is ambiguous. On the one hand, the centralized and hierarchical system of relations between the federal and regional layers appreciably enslaves the lower level in terms of freedom of a legislative and even a procedural act. It shows the absence of the autonomous competences which regions could have had. Nonetheless, there are several shared and exclusive federal competences opening some space for regions to maneuver. So, there are still procedural and regulatory frameworks like tariffs of RES-E or RE promotion responsibility creating the legal and logical basis for regions to participate and influence the sphere of RE in Russia.
Notwithstanding, it is important to shed some light on the informal side of the sphere which is, by the rule, also the part of `power vertical' system. There is almost no literature on the topic of informal agreements between the federal and regional levels in electricity sphere. But we can logically conclude that the renewable energy policies do not belong to the spheres where regional authorities have to show their loyalty and order. These are social policies, elections, and strikes. However, we cannot say so about consequences that these policies can entail like an increase in electricity price. That is why, we can suggest that the Kremlin is more or less indifferent to renewable energy sphere in regions unless it affects electorates' comfort zones by increases in electricity prices. Smeets, Niels. 2017. Op. Cit. 101: 140.; Boute, Anatole, and Alexey Zhikharev. 2019. Op. Cit. 1. Only in such case it can become a risky situation for the sub-federal elites. All other means are dependent on the informal agreements, ties of the regional governments with the federal center which can both reward a region with an appropriate support and punish it with a political dismissal, as Gel'man and Busygina see it. Busygina, Irina. 2016. Op Cit. 113.; Gel'man, Vladimir, and Sergei Ryzhenkov. 2011. Op. Cit.
After having reviewed how the federal system in Russia works, what the constitutional division between layers of power is, and whether the regions in Russia have sufficient regulatory power to influence renewables' promotion at all, we can move to the key part of the chapter devoted to the capacity-based renewable energy supportive mechanism in Russia and all its features.
1.3 The policy process: Russia's capacity-based renewable energy support scheme
In spite of the critical opinion about the renewable energy industry in Russia as about a weak and small industry in the resource-endowed country, renewables in Russia have a long political and legal history. This history resulted in a development of Russia's renewable energy support scheme by the Government in order to “diversify Russia's energy mix, catch up with Western renewable technologies, reduce transportation and fuel costs and reduce GHG emissions”. Smeets, Niels. 2017. Op. Cit. 101: 140. It needs to be said that initially there had been a premium scheme of renewables support which was later replaced by the capacity-based support scheme, lately called the CRESS. Ibid.; Boute, Anatole. 2013. Op. Cit. 15.
The CRESS implies that “a maximum installed capacity of solar, wind and small hydro projects could obtain financial guarantees on Russia's wholesale electricity market” annually. Smeets, Niels. 2017. Op. Cit. 101: 140. In contrast to its predecessor, the premium scheme introduced in 2008, the CRESS, in other words, remunerates the availability of RE plants to generate electricity, but not their key performance production of energy. This newer scheme was introduced in 2011 by the amendment of the 2003 Federal Electricity Law and the adoption of the GD on the CRESS in 2013. The Government of the Russian Federation thus aims to define the essence of the new mechanism, its orders of action and goals: to build “5.426GW of renewable energy facilities, including 3.276GW from wind, 1.759GW from solar power and 0.389GW from hydro by 2024”. Ibid. Needless to admit that the premium scheme - despite its earlier engineering - never saw the horizons of an implementation because of the high political disputes around the renewable sphere in Russia per se. Boute, Anatole, and Alexey Zhikharev. 2019. Op. Cit. 4. Smeets says in his research that there are no determined reasons why the premium scheme was not implemented, but he thinks that the key reason was in gas and oil industries opposition. Smeets, Niels. 2017. Op. Cit. 101: 140.However, we cannot say so about its successor which was already practically launched in 2013.
The Government set a special body called the Administrator of the Trading System (ATS) to manage and supervise the CRESS actual implementation. Thus, it states that the order of action of the CRESS implies the organization of annual tenders in which “companies are invited to place bids for RES projects to be commissioned in the subsequent four years”. Smeets, Niels. 2017. Op. Cit. 101: 140.: “Thus, in 2013 a tender had been organised for projects to be realised by the end of 2014 through 2017”. Boute also adds that winners of the tender which have the lowest capital expenditure (CAPEX) are rewarded with the governmental guarantee to sell their capacity (on a mandatory basis) over 15 years with a pinned price. Boute, Anatole. 2013. Op. Cit.; Smeets, Niels. 2017. Op. Cit. 101: 140.: “a pinned price - a preferential price which ensures a 14% return on investment”. The 2013 GD also requires RE producers to meet a threshold of a local content requirement (LCR) in each plant for each renewable energy type. Governmental Decree N449 “O mekhanizme stimulirovaniya ispol'zovaniya vozobnovlyayemykh istochnikov energii na optovom rynke elektricheskoy energii i moshchnosti”. 2013. It means that investors have to use, to a certain extent, an equipment for a construction which is produced in Russia. It should (originally) improve the local outdated systems and rise the domestic producers' value. It is interesting that those who are not able to reach LCR will be punished by financial penalties.
By now, it can be seen that the RE sphere is comparatively new for Russia and is only in the developmental stage. We can see the same with regard to the CRESS which is the byproduct of political contestation and economic necessity. Some authors proclaim in their research that both the sphere and its main instrument can be already barely named successful due to two stumbling blocks. The first one is that, the Russian government had overestimated its quantitative forecast to reach 4.5% of RE share up until 2020 and consequently decreased the goal to 2.5% until 2024. It creates an embryo of further uncertainty of new investors in terms of stability and investment attractiveness because it shows a close link between the RE sphere and politics. Smeets, Niels. 2017. Op. Cit. 101: 141. The second one is connected with LCR which becomes an obstacle which is hard to overcome because the Russian industry of RE equipment is not developed. Boute, Anatole, and Alexey Zhikharev. 2019. Op. Cit. 4.
To connect the unexpected turn in the Russian energy strategy in 2008 and the intermediate results of the CRESS as a policy explaining the circumstances in which it was engineered we have to use policy cycle stages for a description: (1) agenda-setting; 2) policy formulation; 3) decision making; 4) policy implementation; 5) evaluation. Ibid. We will start with the first stage - we will look at the moment when support schemes for renewables were on the goal setting phase of the policy process.
1.3.1 The agenda setting stage
In 2009, the afore-mentioned first quantitative renewable energy incorporation goal was set by the Russian government, stating that 4.5% of the total electricity generation has to be provided by RE. Smeets, Niels. 2017. Op. Cit. 101: 141. Such an unconventional turn in the state's energy strategy was due to several reasons. First, the global financial crisis and the oil prices' enormous decrease made Russia reconsider its energy strategy in response to gas and oil-oriented energy security in the country. Merlevede and the coauthors say that Russia needed to diversify its energy supply by introducing a new energy mix - a renewable one. Merlevede, Bruno, Koen Schoors, and Bas Van Aarle. 2009. "Russia From Bust To Boom And Back: Oil Price, Dutch Disease And Stabilisation Fund". Comparative Economic Studies 51 (2): 213-241. What is more, in this same year the Ministry of Energy of Russia highlighted a necessity to “save fossil fuels for next generations and to improve the reliability of power supply to local businesses”. Smeets, Niels. 2017. Op. Cit. 101: 142. Yet, the old-fashioned catch up with the Western technological process was also named as one of the reasons to launch such a goal. Ibid.: “this [support scheme] program has been launched solely to support domestic competence and, in particular, to keep up with the scientific-technical revolution in the energy sector, especially renewables” - First Deputy Minister of Energy and chairman of the Russia's oil company Bashneft Aleksey Teksler”. The fact that many politicians and high-ranked businessmen admit the importance of the renewable supply introduction (even from the oil spheres - the direct opposition supposedly) indicates that the decision was made first and foremost politically - Smeets concludes. Ibid.
All the political and economic factors, despite the constraining institutional factors (a possible mild fossil fuels industry opposition) which had been luckily bypassed by the newborn policy allowed it to move to a second stage - a policy design phase.
1.3.2 The policy formulation stage
Logically, it is insufficient to just set a goal without introducing any instruments for its achievement. To reach the desired energy mix with renewable energy therein, the Government decided that a market support scheme for the green energy was necessary. Smeets, Niels. 2017. Op. Cit. 101: 143. However, despite the fact that the new sphere is highly politicized, the institutional opposition represented by fossil fuels electricity producers still exists. These producers do not allow the electricity prices to increase dramatically in order not to destabilize Russian citizens' comfort zone which is necessary for the federal center. Ibid. In other words, it is sort of a political tradeoff between the federal authorities and fossil energy producers. An introduction of a new way of electricity production implies a possible increase in the energy prices, which leads to a dissatisfaction of the peaceful and loyal electorate. Ibid. The task of a new scheme's introduction was burdened with the task of making it insensitive to prices, which entails a creation of a subsidizing scheme. Ibid. The CRESS was thus designed to allow the state to “keep control over quantity and price of RES projects thereby minimizing the risk of electricity price hikes”. Vasileva, Evgeniia, Satu Viljainen, Pekka Sulamaa, and Dmitry Kuleshov. 2015. "RES Support In Russia: Impact On Capacity And Electricity Market Prices". Renewable Energy 76: 82-90.
Подобные документы
Barack Hussein Obama and Dmitry Medvedev: childhood years and family, work in politics before the presidential election and political views, the election, the campaign and presidency. The role, significance of these presidents of their countries history.
курсовая работа [62,3 K], добавлен 02.12.2015Study of legal nature of the two-party system of Great Britain. Description of political activity of conservative party of England. Setting of social and economic policies of political parties. Value of party constitution and activity of labour party.
курсовая работа [136,8 K], добавлен 01.06.2014Analysis of Rousseau's social contract theory and examples of its connection with the real world. Structure of society. Principles of having an efficient governmental system. Theory of separation of powers. The importance of censorship and religion.
статья [13,1 K], добавлен 30.11.2014Телевизионная компания Russia Today как одна из крупнейших поставщиков информации на российском и мировом медиарынке. Формирование образа антигероя в средствах массовой информации. Исследование политической ситуации в Украине за последний период времени.
доклад [14,5 K], добавлен 11.11.2014Review the controversial issues of the relationship between leadership and hegemony in international relations, especially in the context of geostrategy of the informal neo-empires. The formation of a multipolar world order with the "balance of power".
статья [64,7 K], добавлен 19.09.2017Сравнительный метод в политической науке. Определение степени зависимости результатов политики от лидеров. Виды сравнительных исследований: "Case-study", бинарное, региональное, глобальное и кросс-темпоральные сравнения. Виды и уровни переменных.
реферат [26,0 K], добавлен 22.12.2009The situation of women affected by armed conflict and political violence. The complexity of the human rights in them. Influence of gender element in the destruction of the family and society as a result of hostilities. Analysis of the Rwandan Genocide.
реферат [10,9 K], добавлен 03.09.2015Ukraine is an energy-rich republic. Renewable energy installed capacities. Geothermal energy refers to the heat within the earth’s surface that can be recovered and used for practical purposes. Potential for wind power and Solar energy, their use.
эссе [146,3 K], добавлен 20.03.2011Climate change risks for energy sector companies, climate change governmental, institutional policies impact on energy companies operations. Energy companies reactions to climate change issues: strategies, business decisions. Adapting to climate change.
курсовая работа [1,0 M], добавлен 23.10.2016The study of the history of the development of Russian foreign policy doctrine, and its heritage and miscalculations. Analysis of the achievements of Russia in the field of international relations. Russia's strategic interests in Georgia and the Caucasus.
курсовая работа [74,6 K], добавлен 11.06.2012