Political opposition in contemporary Russia: socio-political cleavages and party system in comparative perspective

Concept and measurement political opposition. Hybrid regime: approaches, roots. Configuration of the political opposition in Russia due to the 2018 presidential elections' content analysis. The structural factors of the incumbent-oppositional relations.

Рубрика Политология
Вид дипломная работа
Язык английский
Дата добавления 07.12.2019
Размер файла 186,1 K

Отправить свою хорошую работу в базу знаний просто. Используйте форму, расположенную ниже

Студенты, аспиранты, молодые ученые, использующие базу знаний в своей учебе и работе, будут вам очень благодарны.

The major counter-assumption would be that not just a sum of factors induce the freedom rate of the country, but also the features of the state policy in general, both with the peculiar development trajectory, can result into the more equal relations between the incumbent and opposition, and thus in choice between the equal interpretation, the Freedom in the World rate variable would matter more, that any other, for the final the opposition strength assessment.

The constitutional rule and the strength of the parliament.

In our sample the three countries represent the different approaches to the organization of the constitutional rule.

Thus, Mexican polity belongs to the group of the Latin American presidential republics, in which the directly elected president alone appoints all the ministers, possess significant and decree power, as well as can intervene within the policy of the federal regions, frequently using the state of the emergency regime. Meanwhile, being already elected for a long 6 year term, the Mexican president is not allowed to run for the elections ever again. As in all the other presidential republics, the Mexican president is not able to dissolve the parliament too.

In Russia the constitutional regime can be seen as the mixed, the parliamentary-presidential one. In such kind of the republic the actual balance depends on the consent between the president and the key coalitions in the parliament: if the opposition controls the absolute majority decisions in the parliament, the parliament dominates; if the president meets the support from the parliament in the most of the cases, thus the president dominates. The additional factor that matters is a party cohesion and the institutions, which favors the last, like the strong federalism, the relevant electoral barrier or the right of the factions to block.

In Ukraine the constitution had been frequently fluctuating between the Supreme Council and the president. In 2006-2010, however, the constitution presumed the coalition of the parliamentary majority to appoint the prime minister upon the submission of the president, and the ministers, upon the divided submission of the president or the prime minister. In other cases, however, Ukraine inherited the frames of the prime minister-presidential regime, set by the 1996 constitution, however, with the practically ensured parliamentary dominance.

As for the parliamentary power, in our study we'll estimate the strength of the parliament variable by the Parliamentary Power index, introduced by S.Fish and M.Kroenig through their fundamental comparative study of the worldwide legislatures in 2000-s. Pushing off the sample of the countries, possessing legislatures and at least minimum of the electoral competition, Fish and Kroenig had examined it by the set of the 32 measured criteria, divided in the four groups, that helped them to count the relative strength of the parliaments without considering the common indexes of the political freedom or the presidential / parliamentary republic dichotomy .

The list of criteria, deduce both from the constitutional frame analysis and the analysis of the additional frames, that ensure their appropriate implementation, includes:

1. The capacity of the parliament alone to impeach the president or replace the prime minister

2. The capacity of the parliamentary deputy to serve as a minister

3. The need of the executive officials to testify before the parliament

4. The capacity of the parliament to conduct the independent investigations of the executive activity

5. The right and the capacity of the parliament to oversight over the military and other agencies of cohesion

6. The appointment of the prime minister by the parliament

7. The need of the approval of the parliament to appoint the ministers

8. The presence of thee weak presidency or no presidency at all

9. The right of the parliament to vote no confidence for the government

As the criteria of the influence over executive group;

10. The parliament's immunity from the dissolution by the president or other executive agency

11. The lack of the decree power by the executive agencies

12. The lack of the veto power by the executive and the judiciary agencies

13. The supremacy of the laws, adopted by the parliament

14. The capacity of the parliament to initiate bills in any jurisdiction

15. The mandatory nature of the expenditure funds, set by the parliament

16. The control of the parliament over its own internal resources

17. The immunity of the parliamentary deputies from arrest

18. The elections of any deputy of the parliament

As the criteria of the institutional autonomy group;

19. The right of the parliament alone to change the constitution

20. The need of the approval of the parliament to start the war

21. The need of the approval of the parliament for the ratification of foreign treaties

22. The capacity of the parliament to grant amnesty

23. The right of the parliament to grant pardon

24. The need of the approval of the parliament to appoint the judiciary

25. The right of the parliament to appoint the central bank

26. The capacity of the parliament to influence the operation of the state-owned media

As the criteria of the specified power group;

27. The regularity of the parliamentary sessions

28. The presence of the personal secretaries for every deputy

29. The presence of the non-secretarial staff members with policy expertise, at least in single number for every deputy

30. The capacity of the deputies to be re-elected without any restrictions

31. The attractiveness of the legislative positions in ration to the executive ones

32. The presence of the high degree of the experienced re-elected deputies within the ruling parties

As the criteria of the institutional capacity group.

The final score, based on the Yes/No marking of the following criteria due to the national parliaments, varies from 0 to 100 of the PPI , thus giving the high, the medium or the law capacity estimation, backed by the failure description, linked with the lack within the specific criteria or within the entire group.

For the three countries we compare, the certain scores are:

· 44 for Mexico

· 47 for Russia

· 59 for Ukraine

According to the comments by Fish and Kroenig, these scores mark not rather strong, but almost considerable authority of parliaments in all of the three cases. Meanwhile, according to Fish and Kroenig, in all the three cases there are minor failures in parliamentary power security, which seems to be responsible for the considerable lag of the three parliaments from those of the democracies.

Thus, the Mexican Congress is rather strong for the frames of the pure presidential republic with no prime minister appointment and no-confidence right, so its score can compete with the Ukrainian and Russian ones. However, the Mexican parliament lacks some important features, common for the legislatures worldwide: thus, the Congress gathers no regular sessions and its deputies possess no immunity from the criminal persecution, but what is more important, there is a ban for the immediate re-elections of the deputies, which both with the ban for the them to serve as the ministers and the short 3-year term, makes the position in legislature not attractive in comparison with those in the executive.

In Russia the Federal Assembly, despite of its strong institutional capacity, has approximately no influence over the executive branch of power, prime minister and policy control, except for the no confidence right. What is more, in other fields of the power intercross it suffers much from the expansive power of the president, including the actual loss of the control over the head of the central bank appointment and funds for its own operation.

Finally, in Ukraine the Supreme Council seemed to be the most balanced, being as strong as the Federal Assembly of Russia, but also possessing the rights of the appointment for the positions of the prime-minister, the ministers, and the head of the central bank, as well as the control over the agenda of the state media.

However, there are some features, according to which the Ukrainian parliament could be seen as a weaker one, as well as the Russian, but not the Mexican, and which were not counted within the PPI index:

Firstly, while estimating the strength of the Ukrainian parliament we need to take into account the instability of the constitution and its significant influence over the strategic behavior of the factions.

Secondly, while estimating the strength of the Russian parliament we need to take into account the practice of the full approval of the presidential initiatives by the United Russia majority, which is highly coordinated not by its own partisan structure, but by the direction from the president's administration. We also need to know, that the second chamber of the parliament, the Federal Council, is not directly elected. What is more, the principles of its formation had been changed periodically, despite of which the executive have always kept much influence over the procedure. At last, we should also mention that in Russia the single president had been ruling the country for the three terms (with a four-year break, when he served as the prime minister), and the dominant party had not been the force, that largely conditioned this.

Thirdly, while estimating the strength of the Mexican parliament we need to take into account, that both the presidential candidates and the most of the ministers had always been elected from the list of the Institutional Revolutionary Party by its meetings and leaders, which had been dominating in the parliament. What is more, the PRI federal dominance had been based on the regional one, and the deputies of the second chamber of the Congress, the Senate, unlike Russia, are directly elected. Finally, as it was mentioned, the Mexican president is also limited by the single term, which can be said about the Ukrainian or the Russian two.

The partisan representation in the national parliaments.

In the last paragraph we had found, that the strength of the parliament depend not only on the institutional framework, but also on the quality of the partisan structures.

One of the key measures, which can reveal the particular feature, is the EPN or the Efficient Number of Parties. It is counted as

Where p is a share of seats, controlled by one party, and n is a total number of parties in parliament. The idea of ENP is to reveal a real number of factions, which can ensure the relative majority (>50% voting) through the different partisan alliances.

Despite the classic ENP index, proposed by M.Laakso and R.Taagepera, there is also a modification by J.Molinar (ENP M), shaped specifically for the estimation of the dominant party systems, counted as

Where is a share of seats, controlled by the largest party in the parliament.

To represent the data for the sample in the most informative way, we have chosen the interval of the 3 decades- the examined decade, the one before the examined decade, and one after for each country. The time line was equate to the 3-year electoral cycle in Mexico.

Table 14

Mexico

Russia

Ukraine

ENP

ENP M

ENP

ENP M

ENP

ENP M

1979

1,77

1,05

1982

1,50

1,05

1985

1,72

1,04

1988

3,03

1,53

1991

2,21

1,21

1994

2,17

1,31

8,26

6,07

13,22

2,91

1997

2,86

1,99

6,08

2,54

13,22

2,91

2000

2,64

2,36

7,96

4,80

6,78

4,31

2003

3,02

2,19

3,71

1,39

6,99

4,96

2006

3,02

2,47

3,71

1,39

3,41

2,42

2009

2,92

1,93

1,92

1,11

3,30

2,65

2012

2,80

1,61

4,09

2,20

2015

2,80

1,61

4,74

2,71

2018

1,67

1,05

4,74

2,71

The final index was counted:

· For Mexico as the average for the 1988, 1991, 1994 and 1997 elections, the control year- 1994, as correspond to the middle of transition from the one-party regime to the electoral democracy;

· For Russia as the average for the 2007, 2011 and 2016 elections, the control year- 2016 as correspond to the examined cycle of the presidential elections;

· For Ukraine as the average for the 1998, 2002, 2006 and 2007 elections, the control year- 2007 as correspond to the period of the prime-minister, elected by the parliament.

Via the final index we have also counted the average for the periods of the electoral democracy- of 1993, 1995 and 1999 elections in Russia and of 2000, 2003, 2006 and 2009 elections in Mexico to compare them with the average for the dominant party times.

Table 15

Mexico

Russia

Ukraine

ENP

ENP M

ENP

ENP M

ENP

ENP M

Average

2,57

1,51

2,13

1,26

5,12

4,14

Control year

2,17

1,31

1,67

1,05

3,30

2,65

Dem. Average

2,9

2,24

7,43

4,47

-

-

To understand, where must we use ENP and where ENP M, we should mark, where do we meet the dominant party case. According to the previously said, the dominant party cases are Russia and Mexico, however, there is a difference between them: while in Mexico we don't have a radical difference between the ENP of the 1990-s and 2000-s, in Russia we can see a dramatic reduction from 7,96 in 2000 to 1,92 (1,11) in 2007 after the United Russia had emerged. In Mexico the relatively significant shifts had happen only in 1979, after the mixed electoral system was introduced, and in 1988, when the trial structure of IRP-PAN-PRD was formed. The important remark would be that while in Mexico the increase of PRD had launched after the 60-year IRP dominance, in Russia and Ukraine it had been decreasing from the first elections till mid-2000-s, although, through the different paths. Meanwhile, we need to mention, that in Ukraine there were also attempts to establish the dominant party, but they didn't influence the ENP fluctuation.

The ENP of Ukraine in the examined period relates to the two-and-a-half party system, according to A.Lijphart, the ENP of Mexico- to the transition from the dominant party rule to two-and-a-half party system, the ENP of Russia- to the transition from the dominant party rule to the one-party rule.

To look on the extra specific of ENP formation, we would examine the organization of the parliamentary elections of the studied periods by the four criteria, including:

· The general type of the electoral system: proportional, mixed or plural-majoritarian;

· The permission for the party blocs to participate in elections;

· The electoral barrier;

· The additional rules of the seat redistribution.

Table 16

Mexico

Russia

Ukraine

System

Barrier

System

Barrier

System

Barrier

1-st elections

Mixed

With Blocs

2%The

35% rule

Prop. /

No

No Blocs

7%

Mixed

With

Blocs

4%

2-nd elections

Mixed

With Blocs

2%

Prop. /

No

No Blocs

7%

Mixed

With

Blocs

4%

3-rd elections

Mixed

With Blocs

2%

Mixed /

No

No Blocs

5%

Prop.

With

Blocs

3%

4-th elections

Mixed

With Blocs

2%

The 8% rule

-

-

Prop.

With

Blocs

3%

As we can see, the lowest electoral barrier exists in Mexico, and it is also low in Ukraine. In Russia the barrier is the highest (but not extremely high), but there is also no party blocs allowed. Additionally, In Russia, in contrast to Mexico, the higher chamber of parliament is not elected directly, and only a half of its deputies are elected by the legislatures. However, in Mexico we see the existence of the additional rules of the seat redistribution: thus, on the 1988 elections still operated the 35% rule- the party, that won the 35% of the seats automatically achieved the majority. For the 1991 elections this rule was banned, however, on the 1997 elections the new one was used- the parties were not allowed to get more than 8% seats from the number they got in the national district by the elections in the single-mandate areas. What is more, the candidates in the single-mandate areas can also be put forward only by the parties.

The cleavages.

The last element, we would use to estimate the strength of the parliament, is the number of cleavages, that induce the sufficient number of parties, needed for the representation of the society.

To estimate the particular number of cleavages we'll follow the logic of R.Taagepera and B.Grofman, who had assumed, that the number of cleavages corresponds to ENP as the ENP index - 1. The second source of our work would be an expert poll, which had been implemented by B.Makarenko and co-authors to reveal the importance of the 8 cleavage dimensions for the post-soviet countries. The third source would be examination of the map of the differences in the regional voting for the parliamentary parties, analyzed through the differences between the programs of those parties.

In a case of Russia we'll observe the results of the 2016 parliamentary and the 2018 presidential elections, added by the information about the dominant party's failures on the regional elections in 2018. According to the data, the regional division in voting is low and generally insufficient, however, there can be found some differences: firstly, the west-north part of Russia is less inclined to vote for the incumbent, and more- for the right-liberal parties in comparison to the rest of the country; secondly, the west-south of Russia is more inclined to vote both for the incumbent and for the left-wing opposition, than the North-West or Siberia; thirdly, the Far East regions are the least inclined to vote for the incumbent, despite the lack of the concrete preferences; finally, the highest support for the incumbent is given in the national republics and the oil and gas regions.

Thus, in Russia we can see at least two-and-a-half cleavage dimensions: in the support of the incumbent, in the right-left preferences, and in the attitude of regions to how the votes shall be distributed. Such the results roughly coincide the conclusion of Makarenko and co-authors, who states that in Russia we have 2 fundamental cleavages: between the left and the right, and between the supporters and the opponents of the incumbent. Meanwhile, they also highlighted the 3 secondary cleavages- between the Centre and the periphery, and by the attitude towards the foreign policy and the post-material values. The last two generally correspond the gap between the more liberal population of the biggest cities and those of the majority of the regions.

Concerning the 2010-s State Duma, we can state, even considering the semi-opposition behavior of the Duma deputies and the high role of the incumbent-set pattern in the fact, that some parties can pass the electoral barriers, and some not, there can be seen a strong influence of the left-wing opposition (The Communist Party, the Fair Russia), the presence of the imperial nationalist one (LDPR), and of the right-liberal, pro-western (Yabloko, RPR-PARNAS) which, being out of Duma, plays a crucial role in the new protest movements and is seen serious enough, to be restrained in its activity by the incumbent.

As the conclusion, we can state, that for Russia the multi-partisan system with at least three parties, would be the most convenient, however, the insufficient difference in the electoral patterns and the dominant party system, highly shaped for the taming and exclusion of the opponents leaves us with the approximate 1,5 ENP.

In Ukraine the results of the 2006 and the 2007 parliamentary elections, compared with those of the president of 2004 and 2010, gives us the more diverse image. Thus, firstly it could be found a strong, constantly reproduced division between the electoral preferences of South-East and North-West, based on the three cleavage dimensions: the choice between the Ukrainian, anti-soviet and the Russian, post-soviet identity, the choice between the pro-Western and the pro-Russian international policy, the choice between the more left-wing and a more right-wing policy. Secondly, even within the major division there could be found some difference: so, the Western-Carpathian regions shows stronger pro-western, nationalist and anti-communist views, that the core of the Ukrainian lands, as well as there is a division between the South-West regions, where some population prefer the North-West candidates and where the results of the more moderate Socialist Party exceeds those of the Communist one, and the Eastern-Donbas regions, where both the Communists and the South-East candidates have the strongest positions.

According to Makarenko and co-authors, Ukraine faces four major cleavages: between the right and the left, between the Centre and the periphery, between the supporters and the opponents of the incumbent, between the pro-western and pro-Russian international policy supporters, and the additional cleavage in the sphere of religion- between the supporters of the Ukrainian and Moscow churches.

On the 2006-2007 elections those cleavages were represented by the Party of Reguions (pro-Russian, East-South, left-wing) and the Yulia Tymoshenko Bloc (pro-western, pro-Ukrainian, North-West) as the main forces, the Our Ukraine-People's Self-Defence Bloc (strongly pro-Ukrainian, right-wing), the Communist and the Socialist parties and the centrists (Lytvyn Bloc) as the auxiliary. Within the 2007-2010 Supreme Council the majority was formed by the coalition of Yulia Tymoshenko Block, the Our Ukraine Block and the Lytvyn Block in 2007-2008, and by the coalition of the Party of Regions, the Communist Party and the Lytvyn Bloc in 2010-2012.

As the conclusion, we can state, that for Ukraine the multi-partisan system with at least four parties, would be the most convenient, however, the coincidence of the main cleavage lines by the uniform electoral pattern, shaped mainly by the fundamental question of the national identity, leaves us with the doubt in the ENP interpretation: would it in practice be closer to 4-3,5 or 3-2,5.

In Mexico the common electoral pattern could be seen from the end of the PRI dominance in late 1980-s till the left-nationalist National Regeneration Movement (MORENA) rise on the 2018 elections. According to this pattern, the Northern regions, which is more urbanized and closer to the USA, the Coastal regions, which posses the major oil reserves, and the capital are fond of voting for PAN- the right-wing, conservative, anti-incumbent party, whereas the more agrarian and poorer regions of the South-East are inclined to vote for the secular-left PRD. The pro-incumbent voting, in contrast, is concentrated in the central regions of the country, expanding and retreating in accordance to the popularity of the PRI.

A major conclusion about the nature of such pattern should be the presence of the two cleavage line, which does really matter- the one between the right and the left, and the one between the supporters and the opponents of the incumbent. Following the same source, we can also name the Centre-periphery, the urban-rural and the religious-secular cleavages as the auxiliary.

On the data of the electoral results we can see, that as the PRI was losing the capacity to keep the right-left equilibrium, to satisfy the regions by the distribution policy, and as the people were losing belief in the unique capacity of the incumbent to solve their problems, the voting was turning against the dominant party:

Table 17

PRI

PAN or the relative bloc

PRD or the relative bloc

1988

50,8%

18,1%

9,5%

1994

50,2%

25,8%

16,7%

2000

36,7%

38,1%

18,9%

Thus as the conclusion we can state, that for Mexico the 2,5 party system is the most convenient, although the well-located dominant party managed to reduce the ENP to 1,5 while the contradictions were less sharp.

The indicators of freedom, linkage and development.

In the last paragraph of our case study we'll just glance through the group of the common parameters, linked with hypotheses of the classical regime studies. In the first part of the paragraph we'll examine the general indicators of economic and political development, in the second part we'll test the linkage / leverage hypothesis by Levitsky and Way.

a)The general indicators of the development.

According to the Freedom of the World report, Ukraine of 2000-s belongs to the free / partly free polities (being a flawed democracy according to the Economist Democracy index), Mexico of the 1990-s belongs to the partly-free polities, and Russia of 2010-s belongs to the not free polities (being a soft authoritarian regime according to the Economist Democracy index). That means, we must assume, that the incumbent-opposition relations are the closest to the electoral pluralism, and in Russia- the least close, which assumption we can generally confirm.

According to the Economy Freedom index by Heritage the three countries both posses the medium level of the economy freedom, however Mexico of 1990-s had better protection of property, Russia of 2010-s had better rate of business freedom, and Ukraine of 2000-s- the better rate of trade freedom. The Corruption Perception Index is one of the highest for all the sample, and thus we need to consider that either the methodology of the particular indexes doesn't represent the certain parameters exactly, or the certain parameters are not significant for our study

By the economy structure, the three countries differ much by the share of the oil and gas rate in the state budget. The highest degree of the oil dependence posses Russia, staying on the same level as Mexico in 1980-s, equal to the 8-9%. In Mexico of 1990-s, however, the oil rent achieve only the 3% share, and in Ukraine- less than 1%. If the statistics is correct, we should assume, that the certain parameter matters much for the degree of political pluralism.

Taking the picture broader, Russia posses the highest level of GDP per capita, four times higher than those of the 1990-s Mexico and 2000-s Ukraine, that are practically equal to each other. What is more, Russia posses the highest human capital parameters, however both Mexico and Ukraine are also rather developed societies.

Ukraine, in contrast to Mexico and Russia, is a country with the high level of income equality.

Mexico, in its term, posses the highest level of the post-material, but also of the traditional values, according to the World Value Survey.

The following results mean that in our sample the general pattern of the income / human development - freedom correlation, formed by the Lipset hypothesis, doesn't work, or even represents negatively. Meanwhile, it can also mean that the additional parameters, like equality and value orientation, both with the historical dynamics of GDP growth, can be the variables, that really explain the difference.

Thus, by the GDP dynamics, in 2010-s Russia have been suffering from the stagnation, however, the polity of 2010-s was formed not just in those times, but via the boom of 2000-s, when the economy was growing about a 7% per year after the transition-time decline of 1990-s. In Ukraine the same pattern was seen, but with the position, that the growth stage had launched earlier, than the attempt to build the dominant party was taken. In Mexico, however, the pattern was much different: in 1980-s country suffered the dramatic decline, but under the rule of the dominant party, while in 1990-s the economic recovery coincided the liberalization of the political sphere.

Taking into account the resource-export element of the Russian growth of 2000-s, we'll make a conclusion, that between the mentioned factors in accordance to the certain group of the middle-developed countries, the share of the oil and gas rate in the state budget, the historical context (the political surface) of the GDP dynamics, and, maybe, the parameters of the development, like dominant values and the economic equality, do show stronger correlation with the formation of more or less transparent, competitive incumbent-opposition relations, than the more common indicators of GDP per capita or human development.

The second conclusion would be, that the small sample of the case-study format do also matter for the results, we get by the general indicators' measurement.

b)The linkage / leverage hypothesis.

The foreign linkage and leverage are the additional parameters, that posses the especial meaning. Estimated by the dimension of foreign linkage and leverage:

· Mexico has a strong linkage with the USA via the common border, the high share of the common trade and the USA leadership in the region. However, the foreign leverage is restricted by the scope of the country and the scale of its social problems, including poverty and criminal engagement.

· Russia has medium linkage with Europe, however, its quality varies to the region: while it can be fixed in the big cities, it is absent in the rest of the country. What is more, as a big world power Russia faces no foreign leverage, and from the mid 2000-s it was making efforts to reduce the foreign linkage as well.

· Ukraine has strong linkage with Europe and a common border with EU, however, that linkage lacks required quality. The partial compensation of the last can be found in the medium level of foreign leverage. Meanwhile, not only EU promotes its linkage and leverage to Ukraine, but also Russia, and that division correlates strongly with the polarization of the electoral pattern.

The significance of the leverage/ linkage indicators are clearly seen by the comparison of Russia and Ukraine via their influence on the dominant party project success, in case of Russia, and failure, in case of Ukraine. However, the difference between Russia and Mexico, the two dominant party regimes, is rather unclear due to the real significance of the linkage / leverage influence. As we will assume, considering the anti-democratic tendencies in Russia of 2010-s, the clear difference emerges when the country passes to the articulate policy of democratic linkage restriction- in this case the perfect inaccessibility for the foreign leverage do really matter, as it is in case of Russia or China and Iran.

Conclusion

The general goal of our research was to understand, what factors had determined the difference between the paths of Russia, Mexico and Ukraine in the sphere of the incumbent-opposition relations. The superior goal of our research was to explain the contemporary pattern of the incumbent-opposition relations in Russia by the application of external, institutional logic. The additional goal of our research was to verify the validity of the conclusion by the extension of the particular logic of explanation on the entire sample.

Leaning on the particular results, we can name the list of the factors, that are seen to be important for the particular explanation. Firstly, we should mention a group of the institutional factors: a) the constitution, formed both by the formal and informal norms and practices, and b) the formula of checks and balances, its strength and efficiency. Secondly, we should mention the group of the structural factor, including a) the cleavage structure by its application to the political spectrum in parliament and the geographical division of the country b) the level of budget dependence from the resource export, additionally backed by the dynamics of GDP, GDP per capita and GINI index, observed on the background of the regime transformation c) the level of foreign linkage and leverage, including the direction of their influence on the decision making process in ratio to institution building and political stability.

Concerning concrete variables, we can state confidently that in our sample the stronger parliaments were generally correlating with the more democratic regimes (taking into account that the strength of the parliament can be examined in the different ways, that the informal practices also matter, and that the positions, strongly tied with the formula of checks and balances, should be considered as the most important, which was absent in PPI index). The opposite correlation was found for the bigger lag between the smaller ENP and the larger number of cleavages. According to the three cases, the geographical polarization of cleavages can be counted as generally favorable for the political competition and generally obstructive for the dominant party building. The larger share of oil and gas export, in contrast, can be seen as favorable for the dominant party building and generally harmful for the political competition. Additionally, for the consistent vision of the cases, we must assume that the subjective perception of the social welfare, determined by the correlation of GDP and regime dynamics, do also matter.

To see the influence of the particular factors it is useful to summarize the examination of the incumbent-opposition relations within the three countries.

Thus, in Russia the regime had evolved from the political pluralism of 1990-s and the semi-competitive dominant party regime of 2000-s to the generally non-competitive electoral authoritarianism of 2010-s. In Ukraine the regime had been fluctuating permanently from wide pluralism to the dominant party building, however, all the attempts to concentrate power had been interrupted by the new elections or mass protests. In Mexico the regime trajectory was different: although in mid-XX-th century the regime had been totally non-competitive, the modernization process led to the extension of competition, and after 1980-s it happened a substantial liberalization both in political life and economy that made Mexico to evolve towards democracy till early 2000-s.

To understand the certain picture we must look on the factors.

Thus, among the three countries we have the strongest parliament in Ukraine, however Ukraine doesn't possess a strong formula of checks and balances, as the political system suffers from the repeating revision of constitution, disintegration of parties and coalitions. In Mexico, in contrast, the weak position of the parliament, according to some additional characteristics, like the ban for the reelection of the deputies, was compensated strongly by the firm and sophisticated formula of checks and balances, aimed to prevent the presidential dictatorship. In Russia , the main object of our study, the most essential feature, which seems to determine the particular dynamics of the incumbent-opposition relations, had been a weak or almost absent formula of checks and balances in relation to the authority of the president, on which all the informal practices were based on. Thus, as the State Duma was not as strong constitutionally as the Ukrainian one, such configuration induced the tragic consequences for the evolution of the political pluralism in Russia.

Concerning cleavages, in Russia the cleavages appeared to be not strong enough because of two reasons: firstly, they have been rather numerous for the statist, oil-rich society to be reconciled by the incumbent, and secondly, they have not been tied with the regional borders. To illustrate this thesis, we can, compare the 2010-s Russia with itself of 1990-s, which political configuration was influenced strongly by the sharp conflict between the communists, with a core support in the agrarian "Red Belt" regions, and the democrats, with a core support on the urbanized north. Additionally we'll state that one of the reasons why is the right opposition ignored by the incumbent is its strong geographical connection with the big cities, which can't be seen relatively to the parliamentary parties. In contrast to Russia, the Mexican politics had been determined strongly by a single, but rather strong, geographically tied conflict between the right and the left politicians: thus, when the dominant party had lost an opportunity to act both on the two sides of the conflict, relying on the Keynesian model of growth and broad redistribution, it failed. In Ukraine the number of cleavages was higher, and most of them were geographically tied, so even with the attempts to polarize the country by the smaller number of dimensions, the dominant parties had failed to establish themselves in this country.

According to the theoretical expectations, concerning the concept of "oil curse", the share of oil and gas rent in state budget is correlating strongly with a degree of the political freedom in our sample: thus if the formation of Russian authoritarianism had happened in a time of high oil prices, the failure of the Mexican one was pushed by their sharp decline. Additionally, both dominant party regimes- in Russia and Mexico,- had been formed in the countries with a large share of oil export. In Ukraine- the most competitive state, in contrast, the export of the natural resources haven't played an important role in the economy. Finally, among the two non-competitive regimes of our sample- Russia and Mexico,- it was a one with the lowest share of natural, which incumbent had started to lose its hegemony strongly after the sharp fluctuation of prices.

The linkage / leverage hypothesis had also been confirmed according to our study. If Russia- the most authoritarian country- was found to be the farther from the borders of the "democratic West" and the most self-sufficient within the world order, Ukraine- the most competitive one,- possessed the opposite characteristics. Meanwhile, in cases of Ukraine and Mexico there could be used an alternative explanation: not just the influence of the democratic state, but the effect of the competition- of pro-western and pro-Russian policy in Ukraine, of the American-right and the American-left outlooks in Mexico. However, the crucial fact is that the two countries in sample, which were affected by the significant impact of the linkage / leverage factor had not opposed democratization tendencies strongly, unlike Russia.

What was surprising is that according to our findings the conventional variables like the Human Capital index, GDP per capita, the spread of the post-material values or GINI index were not found to influence the level of the political freedom in our sample, or the connection is rather ambiguous. Meanwhile, the clear correlation can be seen between the GDP dynamics and the support for the non-competitive regime, and thus for the strength of the incumbent in relation to the oppositional actors. So, both Russia and Ukraine suffered the dramatic decrease of GDP in 1990-s, however when the economy started recovering rapidly, Ukraine still had the same hybrid regime with the wide range of pluralism, while Russia had shifted towards the dominant party rule practically at the turning point. What about Mexico, its one-party regime was rather strong while the economy was growing rapidly, but the crisis of 1982 made the regime weaker and pushed the incumbent towards political liberalization. However, just after the pluralism increased, the economy started to grow, and thus the democratization had faced no serious obstacles.

So, to conclude, we can state, that in Russia the contemporary configuration of the incumbent-opposition relations, characterized by the dominance of the incumbent and the unfair rules of the game on the background of the formal maintenance of the democratic mechanisms, have been determined by the group of factors, including:

1. The fusion of the formally substantial parliament with the weak formula of checks and balances and the kind of informal constitution, that overpowers the presidential authority.

2. The numerous, but not sharp and not geographically tied cleavages, which let the dominant party to exist safely, while the redistribution and conviction mechanisms work, and ignore opposition.

3. The high share of oil & gas rent in the state budget and the GDP dynamics, characterized by the deep crisis in the period of political pluralism and the boom in the time of the dominant party formation.

4. The low level of foreign linkage and leverage, promoted by the democratic countries, determined both by the geographical and geopolitical features of the country.

In contrast, in Mexico and Ukraine the situation was different, and thus was the state of opposition and the dynamic of the political regimes.

The conclusion

The work we had done had considered the four research question and the set of the particular problems.

The general goal of our research was to find:

· What types of opposition do exist in Russia?

· What was the dynamics, that had formed such a pattern?

· What combination of factors had formed such the pattern and the dynamics?

· How does this correspond to the formation of incumbent-opposition relations in other regimes of the competitive authoritarian / hybrid type?

While implementing of our research we also tried to answer the questions like:

· Is it possible to use the explanations and categories, elaborated in the different political environment, to represent the Russian politics correctly?

· How do the role and position of the Russian opposition correspond to the competitive authoritarian / hybrid regime frames?

· Is it possible to forecast the changes in the behavior of the political opposition in Russia after the possible changes of the institutional / socio-economic frames of Russian politics, basing on the certain comparison and classification?

As for the first question, in Ch.3 we had found the presence of the three main groups of opposition, basing on the the Lipset-Rokkan cleavage theory:

· A group of the conditionally right forces, united by the right-wing economic agenda and democratic orientation, by the stronger support for the federalism, free trade and freedom of culture, by the promotion of the peaceful policy course, the negation of the imperial ideology and the support of the liberal rhetoric.

· A group of the conditionally left forces, who support the left social and economic agenda and the protectionist measures, whose ideological frames are based on the symbols of the USSR and the socialist idea.

· A group of the conditionally "third way" forces, supporting the Russian ethnocentrism, the left social agenda, the protectionist measures and the imperial rhetoric- the forces, which perceive the so-called transnational cleavage as the most crucial one.

What is more, basing on the Dahl's typology of opposition, we have revealed the certain connections:

· Most of the conditionally right parties belong to the classical opposition, also concerning the features, that refer to the principle and personnel.

· The conditionally left parties, on contrary, follows no single pattern, being in average less radical than the conditionally right ones: the most representative case in this group is CPRF, which orientation fluctuates from the classical to semi-opposition dependent on the issue and situation.

· In contrast, the conditionally "third way" parties were found to follow the most moderate, personal or the semi-opposition orientations.

What we have also found, is that the political position of the oppositional candidate depends much on such factors, like the scale of the party or the agenda:

· Thus, an only consistently principal opposition candidate of our sample- Alexei Navalny,- was found to posses such the attributes, as the political connection with the third sector and mass-media, the orientation on the recent (2010-s) cleavage agenda, an active participation in protest and street politics. Simultaneously, all those attributes were found to correlate with the higher oppositional radicalism, the incumbent's suspicion and the conditionally right parties in general.

· In contrast, the parliamentary status, the support of the large party and orientation on the old (1990-s) cleavage agenda were found to correlate with the firm inclusion in the political system, the conditionally left or third wave agenda and less degree of the oppositional radicalism.

Finally, what we have also found, that the appearance and the strategic behavior of the political opposition on the elections and beyond corresponds much to their characteristics according to the particular factors:

· Thus, among the politicians of the 2018 election's sample, Alexei Navalny was found to act strongly to delegitimize the rule of the incumbent before and after the elections, being also not admitted to the elections by the authorities.

· CPRF and LDPR- the parties, which posses all the attributes of the second group- were found to be strategically flexible in their relations with the incumbent, basing on the strong party structures. Their strategic goal on the elections are seen rather clear- to emphasize their strength and to maintain the core of their electorate .

· All other parties and candidates, participating in the 2018 elections, except for YABLOKO, which had belonged to the second group in 1990-s, and is staying near the first group nowadays, were found to demonstrate weak activity before and after the elections, to posses the limited resources and to pursue rather vague goals in their electoral campaigns. In other words, to have no significance in Russian politics.

As for the second question, in Ch.1 and 4 we have traced the transformation of the Russian regime and party system and thus had found, that the main dynamics from the 1990-s till 2010-s was the limitation of the political pluralism and competition, followed by the formation of the facade (imitative) party system and the ideocratic elite consolidation, through which the strong position in parliament was kept only by those two opposition parties, who had kept it and who also agreed to welcome the statist-illiberal social contract of Putin's administration. On the regime level it was a transformation towards from the electoral democracy of 1990-s towards the hybrid regime of 2000-s- the one, where the elections are unfair, but still can be won by the opposition,- and the competitive autocracy of 2010-s- the regime, where the space for the limited competition exists, but the structure of power is entirely submitted to the authoritarian framework. On the level of the opposition party behavior such a framework sets the clear border between the parties, who agree to follow the rules, set by the incumbent, who see it as a way to fix their monopoly even by the price of the oppositional radicalism decrease, and those, who don't or just can't and thus are doomed for the decline or sharp confrontation with the autocrat and his dominant party.

As for the third question, to understand, how had the contemporary configuration of the incumbent-opposition relations been formed an what factors had influence its formation in the particular way. To complete such a goal we made the comparison of the 2010-s Russia with the 2000-s Ukraine and the 1990-s Mexico and had found, that Russian path towards the competitive authoritarianism had been determined by:

· The fusion of the formally substantial parliament with the weak formula of checks and balances and the kind of informal constitution, that overpowers the presidential authority.

· The numerous, but not sharp and not geographically tied cleavages, which let the dominant party to exist safely, while the redistribution and conviction mechanisms work, and ignore opposition.

· The high share of oil & gas rent in the state budget and the GDP dynamics, characterized by the deep crisis in the period of political pluralism and the boom in the time of the dominant party formation.

· The low level of foreign linkage and leverage, promoted by the democratic countries, determined both by the geographical and geopolitical features of the country.

In contrast, the impact of those factors in Ukraine and Mexico were found to lead the first country towards the maintenance of the more democratic regime, and the second- to the formation of one-party rule, which, however, was found to be fragile while meeting with the society transformation and the financial crisis, which pushed it to liberalization. So, answering the fourth question, we might say, that Russian case is much explained by the application of the hybrid regime / electoral authoritarianism theory, meanwhile, the current state of the incumbent-opposition relations in Russia can't be deducted by the belonging to the particular kind of regime as such.

Responding the additional research questions, we would state, that there are enough instruments to forecast the approximate behavior of the political opposition in Russia, including the application of classifications of the political opposition and the comparative analysis. Thus, basing on our research, we would state approximately, that no serious change is likely to occur in incumbent-opposition relations without the serious shifts within the constitutional formula, connected with the political reforms, the transition of power or the erosion of the ruling coalition, or without the transformation of the cleavage map of the country, that will make impossible to keep the 1990-s cleavage agenda or to avoid the geographical ties of cleavages, or without the serious decrease in the solidity of the oil & gas based rent system, the change of the attention towards the foreign linkage or the increase of the vulnerability from the leverage of foreign democracies. What we can also assume is that the behavior of the key opposition actors within the next electoral circle, by any scenario, would be largely determined by their position in the current configuration, in which they are essentially polarized not just by the cleavage position and the degree of the radicalism, but by the facts of the partisan (non)representation in parliamentary or of the (non)recognition by the incumbent.

So, to conclude, we should say, that the goal, set for this study, have been successfully. As for the aims, set for the each chapter, all of them had been successfully completed either.

To conclude entirely, we just want to fix some research paradoxes and opportunities met through our research:

· The first opportunity concerns the expansion of our opposition studies on the parliamentary and regional elections;

· The second one, which seems to be more interesting, considers the expansion of the hybrid regime study on the broader sample of the countries, as well as on sample, including more cases of the electoral authoritarianisms, added by the still forming hybrids to examine the real space of opportunities for the incumbent-opposition relations diversity;

· Finally, there is a paradox concerning the debatable field of the cleavage measurement, which scientific base is now going through the revision because of the 2010-s electoral shifts in Europe and the Americas. In our opinion, to follow the actual trajectory of the world political studies it would be reasonable to update our knowledge about the cleavages in Russia addressing to the debates.


Подобные документы

  • Study of legal nature of the two-party system of Great Britain. Description of political activity of conservative party of England. Setting of social and economic policies of political parties. Value of party constitution and activity of labour party.

    курсовая работа [136,8 K], добавлен 01.06.2014

  • The classical definition of democracy. Typical theoretical models of democracy. The political content of democracy. Doctrine of liberal and pluralistic democracy. Concept of corporate political science and other varieties of proletarian democracy.

    реферат [37,3 K], добавлен 13.05.2011

  • The term "political system". The theory of social system. Classification of social system. Organizational and institutional subsystem. Sociology of political systems. The creators of the theory of political systems. Cultural and ideological subsystem.

    реферат [18,8 K], добавлен 29.04.2016

  • The definition of democracy as an ideal model of social structure. Definition of common features of modern democracy as a constitutional order and political regime of the system. Characterization of direct, plebiscite and representative democracy species.

    презентация [1,8 M], добавлен 02.05.2014

  • Basis of government and law in the United States of America. The Bill of Rights. The American system of Government. Legislative branch, executive branch, judicial branch. Political Parties and Elections. Freedom of speech, of religion, and of the press.

    презентация [5,5 M], добавлен 21.11.2012

  • Referendum - a popular vote in any country of the world, which resolved important matters of public life. Usually in a referendum submitted questions, the answers to which are the words "yes" or "no". Especially, forms, procedure of referendums.

    презентация [1,2 M], добавлен 25.11.2014

  • Leading role Society Gard Kresevo (USC) in organizing social and political life of the Poland. The Polish People's Movement of Vilna Earth. The influence of the Polish Central Electoral Committee. The merger of the TNG "Emancipation" and PNC "Revival".

    реферат [18,3 K], добавлен 02.10.2009

  • Analysis of Rousseau's social contract theory and examples of its connection with the real world. Structure of society. Principles of having an efficient governmental system. Theory of separation of powers. The importance of censorship and religion.

    статья [13,1 K], добавлен 30.11.2014

  • Barack Hussein Obama and Dmitry Medvedev: childhood years and family, work in politics before the presidential election and political views, the election, the campaign and presidency. The role, significance of these presidents of their countries history.

    курсовая работа [62,3 K], добавлен 02.12.2015

  • The situation of women affected by armed conflict and political violence. The complexity of the human rights in them. Influence of gender element in the destruction of the family and society as a result of hostilities. Analysis of the Rwandan Genocide.

    реферат [10,9 K], добавлен 03.09.2015

Работы в архивах красиво оформлены согласно требованиям ВУЗов и содержат рисунки, диаграммы, формулы и т.д.
PPT, PPTX и PDF-файлы представлены только в архивах.
Рекомендуем скачать работу.