Testing Fama-French Model on Russian Stock Market

The problematic stocks in the five-factor model is the small stock with negative exposures. The average returns of the small firms that invest a lot despite low profitability. The intercept of the big stocks which invest a lot despite low profitability.

Рубрика Маркетинг, реклама и торговля
Вид курсовая работа
Язык английский
Дата добавления 14.09.2018
Размер файла 274,6 K

Отправить свою хорошую работу в базу знаний просто. Используйте форму, расположенную ниже

Студенты, аспиранты, молодые ученые, использующие базу знаний в своей учебе и работе, будут вам очень благодарны.

Размещено на http://www.allbest.ru/

Testing Fama-French Model on Russian Stock Market

Table of contents

  • Introduction
  • Motivation
  • Literature Review
  • A three-factor model
  • Three factor model
  • Factors calculation
  • Constructing CAPM model
  • Constructing Fama-French 3 factor model
  • Additional tests
  • Four-factor Model
  • Size-B/M test
  • Size-Momentum portfolios
  • A five-factor model
  • Factors definitions
  • Size-B/M portfolios
  • Size-profitability portfolios
  • Size-investment portfolios
  • Common Patterns
  • Conclusion
  • List of References

Introduction

For more than half a century the economists are trying to find the optimal model that would include the factors which explain the returns of the stocks. Estimation of the returns is the crucial element of the internal valuation of the company's performance. It is also a factor which influences the company's capitalisation and hence, it's attractiveness to investors. So, many economic agents such as managers and investors need to have a model to estimate returns. However nowadays there is no common model that is used by all firms. This is because all existing models have some disadvantages, such as multicollinearity or lack of explaining power. The most basic model - Capital Asset Pricing Model - was extended by economists Eugene Fama and Kenneth French into a multifactor model. In 1993 Fama and French published a paper called "Common Risk Factors in Returns on Stocks and Bonds", where they proposed to account for three factors which influenced the returns on a stock - these factors were risk premium, book-to-market factor and the size factor. Multifactor models faced criticism because the choice of factors is not obvious and there are many factors which are correlated among each other and can create multicollinearity in the model. The economists continued to modify Fama-French model and in 1997 Mark Carhart added a momentum factor which was described as a tendency to rise in the previous month. Later in 2015 Fama and French extended their three-factor model in five-factor model, adding profitability and investment factors. They also claim that their model is country-specific and works best for the developed economies. Though the choice of the factors is quite subjective the three-factor model became one of the most widespread in the finance. In this paper I am going to asses these asset-pricing models on Russian stock market and examine if the three-factor model is a good measure. Then I will extend the model into Carhart four-factor model and Fama-French five-factor model to check if they really improve the original model.

stock factor model

Motivation

Asset pricing models even in the simple forms of three, four, and five variables show many results that are hard to generalize. The results of each research on these models would be subjective to the specificity of data, the restrictions of the model and the methodology. The models are hardly based on economic hypotheses. The goal of asset pricing models nowadays is to technically construct the factors which would best explain the average returns. The goal of this paper is to test the models on Russian stock market, which has never been done using five-factor models and try to conclude whether these results are in line with the US stock market analysis. I will analyze which of the models works best and what conclusions can be made from some specific results, especially on small stocks, which happen to be the biggest issue with all of the asset pricing models. I omitted the detailed methodology of the models in the literature review because I am going to explain these details while working with my data in further sections.

Literature Review

In 1992 Eugene Fama and Kenneth French published a paper called "The Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns". They started the paper with the analysis of Sharpe-Lintner-Black model which proposed that the market portfolio was mean-variance efficient in Markowitz terms. This prediction implied that the expected returns on stocks were linearly dependent from their betas (the slope of the stock return to the market return) and that betas were sufficient to explain the expected returns. Fama and French claimed that there were a few contradictions to the Sharpe-Lintner-Black model. Banz had already discovered the size effect (Banz, 1981). He found out that the Market Equity (ME) was another significant factor along with betas in the explanation of the expected returns. The returns on stocks with high ME were on average too low for their betas and the returns on stocks with low ME were on average too high for their beta. Bhandari later found out that leverage was not included into beta as SLB model claimed but it should had been included as the variable itself along with the size factor and beta (Bhandari, 1988). Stattman, Rosenberg, Reid, and Lanstein analyzed the U. S. stock market and discovered the influence of book-to-market ratio, BE/ME, on expected returns (Rosenberg, Reid, Lanstein, 1985). Later Chan, Hamao, and Lakonishok also found this positive relation on Japanese stock market (Chan, Hamao, Lakonishok, 1991). It was widely argued whether price-earnings ratio, E/P, should be included as a factor. Basu and Ball claimed that E/P absorbs the other factors as a catch-all proxy. No matter what these factors are, high E/P represents higher risk and greater expected return (Basu, 1983). So, the goal of Fama-French 1992 paper was to analyze which of 5 factors - beta, size, book-to-market, leverage and E/P were redundant in predicting expected returns. They found out that size and book-to-market factors were significant in explaining expected returns. They concluded that beta alone did not explain the expected returns on stock and size and BE/ME factors absorbed the effects of leverage and E/P. Fama and French suggested that the stock risks were multidimensional. While ME represented one dimension of risk, BE/ME represented the other dimension of risk. Book-to-market ratio in their opinion could be the factor of relative distress. Firms with bad prospects estimated by the market tend to have higher expected returns than the good prospects. The economic interpretation of the results could be discussed but the statistical result was strong - size and book-to-market were significant factors in explaining expected returns on stocks.

Let's move to the methodology which Fama and French used. They did not include financial firms into data because these firms have too high leverage which is not typical in terms of risk. They also make a two-period gap between accounting data and the returns to ensure that the accounting information is known in the latter period. They claim that the choice of the year-end month does not alter the results. The authors estimate betas the following way: first they divide the stocks into portfolios then estimate betas and assign each beta to the individual stocks from the corresponding portfolios. This approach was introduced by Fama and Macbeth in 1973. Fama and French find that fixing the size betas does not explain the average stock returns. When they included book-to-market ratio and E/P factor, they found that across the portfolios E/P factor has got a U-shape and book-to-market factor shows strong positive relation. Influence of these factors did not steal the influence of beta, because beta alone showed no difference between portfolios. The authors explain that leverage and BE/ME factor are closely linked and suggest two ways to interpret book-to-market effect in average returns. A high BE/ME means that the firms has poor prospects compared to the firms with lower BE/ME. Hence, book-to-market factor accounts for financial distress. Also high BE/ME signals as an involuntary leverage effect. Ball claimed that E/P ratio is a factor which catches all the other risk factors in expected returns (Ball, 1978). However, the size factor eliminates the significance of price earnings factor. The conclusions of Fama and French 1992 paper are quite intermediate: they conclude that beta alone does not explain stock returns and also say that size and book-to-market factors absorb the other factors influencing price. The authors do not suggest the best model explaining stock returns.

However, in 1993 Fama and French published a paper called `Common risk factors in returns on stocks and bonds'. In this paper they identified three factors on stock market: overall market factor, firm size factor and book-to-market equity factor. The authors extended their previous paper in three ways:

They expanded the set of assets returns adding bonds to common stock (U. S.government and corporate bonds)

They expanded the set of explanatory variables. They added term-structure factors to explain bond returns. They hoped that bond and stock returns overlaped and there would be some chance to explain each other.

They changed the approach of testing. Fama and Macbeth approach was useless when applied to bonds because the cross-section returns with size and book-to-market factors were irrelevant for bonds.

Instead they used the approach of Black, Jensen, and Scholes (1972). Returns on stocks and bonds were regressed on returns of mimicking portfolios for size, book-to-market and term-structure factors. The slopes of the regression have much clearer interpretation for both stocks and bonds than just pure size and BE/ME factors.

The authors block the stocks the same as in 1992. Blocking by size divides the stocks to small and big (S and B) by medium size on NYSE. They also break the stock into three groups by book-to-market equity. Lowest 30% are called Low, medium 40% are called Medium, and the highest 30% on NYSE are called High. The intersection of the blocks create six portfolios (S/L, S/M, S/H, B/L, B/M, B/H). Then they create a size factor - SMB (small minus big), which is equal to monthly difference between the average returns on the small stocks and average returns on the big stocks. This factor is free of book-to-market influence because each part of the difference has approximately the same BE/ME. The next factor is book-to-market factor which is called HML (High minus Low). It is equal to the difference of monthly average returns on high BE/ME stocks minus average returns of the low BE/ME stocks. This factor is free from size influence.

In their data Fama and French use 25 portfolios of stocks which are formed by dividing stocks into 5 quintiles by size and 5 quintiles by book-to-market ratio, then intersecting these groups. The smallest size quintile has the most stocks but has the lowest value. The biggest size quintile has the least stocks and is the biggest in value.

Fama and French find that SMB and HML factors alone do not have a high explaining factor, however if we add market risk premium to the regression, R squared increases and all factors become significant. Adding market risk premium almost eliminates the intercept which is high in a two-factor case. So when the intercepts become close to zero it means that the three factors - market risk premium, SML, and HML include almost all common variation in returns and explain the cross-section of average stock returns really well.

So, Fama and French find out that book-to-market ratio is connected to the firms profitability. On average, firms, that have low BE/ME ratio, have higher earnings than the firms with high BE/ME ratio.

Fama and French summarize their paper by saying that the choice of factors is empirical and quite arbitrary: there is no economic theory behind. So there remain open question on why these three factors are chosen to explain average stock returns and what are any other possible combinations of factors which improve the model.

Further, the three-factor model was waiting for the extension. Several economists proposed to add momentum factor into the model, however they suggested different forms of this coefficient. In 1995, Mark Grinblatt, Sheridan Titman, and Russ Wermers published a paper called `Momentum investment strategies, portfolio performance, and herding: a study of mutual fund behaviour'. The paper mainly focused on the behaviour of the mutual funds and how the copied each other. However in the beginning of the paper there is an introduction of the momentum factor, which was later added to Fama and French model. The authors measure the momentum as the average increase in the stock's weight multiplied by its lagged return. The theory behind this measure implies that if a price of a stock has been increasing, it will continue growing. So for the positive return the investors increase the weight of a stock in their portfolio, increasing the momentum factor and for the negative return investors decrease the weight of the stock, causing momentum to increase, too. Grinblatt, Titman and Wermers did not add the momentum factor into the multi-factor model, however they inspired Mark Carhart to do it. Carhart in his paper `On persistence in mutual funds performance' (1997) defines the momentum factor as the equally weighted average of firms with the highest 30 percent eleven-month returns lagged one month minus equally weighted average of firms with lowest 30 percent eleven-month returns lagged one month. Carhart names this factor PR1YR and adds it to Fama and French three-factor model. Carhart finds that high variance in the factors and low cross-correlation help to account for sizeable variation in stocks returns with no multicollinearity effect. Carhart also finds that the four-factor model outperforms the CAPM and the three-factor model in terms of pricing errors. He claims that the three-factor model pricing errors are strongly positive for the winner stock portfolios in the previous year and that the errors are strongly negative for the loser stock portfolios. The four-factor model fixes this problem and reduces mean absolute error from 0.31 percent in the three-factor model to 0.14 percent in the four-factor model.

In 2012 Fama and French published a paper called `Size, value, and momentum in international stock returns', where in terms of momentum they divided the stocks into three groups - winners, neutral and losers (top 30 percent momentum, middle 40 percent, and lowest 30 percent accordingly). The momentum factor is called WML (winners minus losers) and is equal to weighted average of winner stocks minus the weighted average of loser stocks in the previous eleven months. Fama and French constructed the portfolios of all possible combinations of factor types for the deeper analysis. Some of their results were quite disappointing for those who adopted the four-factor model. Examining the returns in the four region which sum up the vast majority of trade (North America, Europe, Japan and Asia Pacific) there was a strong presence of the momentum factor in all regions except Japan. They analyzed the influence of the size factor on momentum returns and found that in Japan there was no momentum for any stock size. The three global models - CAPM, three-factor model, and the four-factor model performed badly when asked to explain average returns on size/BM or size/momentum regional portfolios. Speaking of local models, when the local model is acceptable, the four-factor model outperforms the CAPM and the three-factor models. The local models experience some issues with capturing momentum-size portfolios returns due to extreme values. However, the authors claim that these extreme tilts are in reality rare and would not cause a serious problem in application of the model.

In 2015 Fama and French published a new paper called `A five-factor asset pricing model', where they introduced profitability and investment factors instead of momentum. They state that these factors are present in the dividend discount model which says that the market value of a stock is equal to the discounted value of expected dividends per share. The evidence by Titman, Wei and Xei showed that the three-factor model lacked the variation due to profitability and investment (Titman, Wei, Xei, 2003), so Fama and French introduced these factors. Factor RMW is the difference between the returns on diversified portfolios with robust and weak profitability. Factor CMA is the difference between the returns on diversified portfolios with conservative (low) and aggressive (high) investment firms. They create value-weighted replicating portfolios and combine all factors in three-,four-, and five-factor models. To ease the process they increase the quantiles in most cases to break the factors in less groups. One of the interesting results is that in five-factor model HML factor never improves the model compared to four-factor model without HML. The authors leave the question if this is an anomaly in their data or it would happen internationally. They conclude that the parsimony may be an issue with the five factors and they tend to divide the factors by 2 or 3 in sorting because it both eases the process and shows better results. Fama and French suggest omitting HML variable and checking if it is redundant. However, if it is important for the analysis one can leave value in the model.

The most problematic types of stocks in the five-factor model were the small stock with negative exposures to risk and profitability. It is difficult to explain the average returns of the small firms that invest a lot despite low profitability. Another serious issue is that the intercept of the big stocks which invest a lot despite low profitability is positive. Economic logic struggles to explain some of the results by Fama and French and the authors conclude that again the small stock are the biggest problem in asset pricing model because they show the controversial results.

A three-factor model

Data

Fama and French have an online database with all calculated factors, however, there are no calculations on Russian stock exchange, so I will calculate the factors in this paper. I am taking ordinary stocks of thirty biggest non-financial companies from Bloomberg Database. These companies are:

Table 1. The List of Companies

1) Gazprom

2) Rosneft

3) Lukoil

4) Novatek

5) Nornikel

6) Gazpromneft

7) Tatneft

8) Surgutneftegas

9) NLMK

10) Severstal

11) Yandex

12) RUSAL

13) Polus

14) Magnit

15) Alrosa

16) MTS

17) MMK

18) En+ Group

19) Inter RAO

20) Uralkaliy

21) Bashneft

22) Fosagro

23) Megafon

24) Rusgidro

25) Polymetall

26) PIK

27) FSK-EES

28) VSMPO-AVISMA

29) Rostelekom

30) Rosseti

I do not include financial companies into the model because they have non-typical approach to risk-taking and Fama-French do not include them into the model too. I will be using a nine-year time span, starting from 2008 and ending in 2016. The returns are monthly. Market return is a return of a MICEX market index, and the risk-free rate is the yield of one year Russian zero-coupon bond.

Three factor model

Factors calculation

Fama and French extended the famous one factor CAPM model, where there is only market risk premium, by adding two more factors - size and value. So, three-factor Fama-French 1993 model looks like this

(1)

Where = Monthly return of a stock i,

= Risk-free rate at time t,

= Excess market return at time t,

= Expected return of a size factor at time t,

= Expected return of a value factor at time t.

SMB factor can be interpreted as “small minus big”, and HML as “high minus low”. Each year I calculate the median market equity of a stock. I assume that market equity is equal to price of a stock multiplied by a number of stocks outstanding. If market equity of a stock is lower than the median market equity, then this year the stock is going to be in a group of small stocks (S). If the market equity is higher than the median, then the stock is in the group of big stocks (B). Then I calculate book-to-market ratio for each stock for each year. Book-to-market ratio is equal to book equity divided by market equity. If a stock's book-to-market ratio is lower than the 30% percentile on the market, then this year the stock is going to be in a group of low stocks (L). If BE/ME ratio is higher than the 70% percentile on the market, then the stock is in the group of high stocks (H). Otherwise it is in the group of medium stocks. So, there are two groups based on the size factor and three groups based on the value factor. We intersect these groups to get six portfolios:

Table 2. The List of Portfolios

S/H

Portfolio of small stocks with high BE/ME ratio

S/M

Portfolio of small stocks with medium BE/ME ratio

S/L

Portfolio of small stocks with low BE/ME ratio

B/H

Portfolio of big stocks with high BE/ME ratio

B/M

Portfolio of big stocks with medium BE/ME ratio

B/L

Portfolio of big stocks with low BE/ME ratio

Now, we form factor SMB as the difference of average monthly returns of small stocks portfolios and average monthly returns of big stocks portfolios:

Then we form factor HML as the difference between average monthly returns of high BE/ME portfolios and average monthly returns of low BE/ME portfolios:

We get the following statistics of the three factors, where Risk Premium is the difference between market return and risk-free return:

Table 3. The Factors Statistics

SMB

HML

Risk Premium

Mean

-0,0364

-0,10041

-0,079212933

Median

-0,04993

-0,10357

-0,071855415

Maximum

0,212142

0,380598

0,109900858

Minimum

-0,26085

-0,3655

-0,359041082

Risk Premium may be negative due to low rate of return of the market index compared to risk-free rate of return.

Constructing CAPM model

First of all, I am going to construct the CAPM model for each of the six portfolios. The formula of the CAPM model is the following:

I get the following statistics for each portfolio:

Table 4. CAPM Portfolio Statistics

Portfolio

Constant

Risk Premium

S/H

-0,12786116

(-9,440546537)

1,06826555

(8,525246321)

0,406760108

S/M

0,009148026

(0,927501593)

1,104366083

(12,10234516)

0,580142745

S/L

0,014290438

(1,348370437)

0,995433418

(10,15184823)

0,49296858

B/H

-0,060239184

(-3,944915912)

0,708649066

(4,968205789)

0, 197966484

B/M

0,008773447

(1,806500415)

1,00333028

(22,32960052)

0,82468068

B/L

0,00423434

(0,710607603)

0,840932881

(15,25368124)

0,687015383

The t-statistics are in the parentheses. In the three cases the constant is significantly different from zero. Beta is close to one in all six portfolios is very different among portfolios. I can compare the beta of each portfolio with its mean return:

Table 5. Betas compared to return

Portfolio

Average Return

Beta

S/H

-0,12864

1,06826555

S/M

0,005509

1,104366083

S/L

0,01928

0,995433418

B/H

-0,03177

0,708649066

B/M

0,013137

1,00333028

B/L

0,021462

0,840932881

Graph 1. Betas and return

The graph displays the violation of the CAPM hypothesis that higher beta yields higher return. The graph shows the average returns (not excess returns) of each of the six portfolios and their betas.

CAPM model performs quite poorly on Russian stock market. Low and non-zero constants are the evidence of this model's poor performance. The violation of basic CAPM hypothesis is another nail in the coffin of the model. Now I will move on to testing the three-factor model and checking if it yields better results than CAPM.

Constructing Fama-French 3 factor model

Now, for each of the six portfolios I will construct Fama-French three-factor regression. The formula of the regression is the following:

On the left-hand side I will use the average excess returns on each of the portfolios. Here are the statistics of the models:

Table 6. Portfolios Statistics

Portfolio

Constant

Risk Premium

SMB

HML

S/H

-0,036002209

(-4,286986826)

0,869969958

(15, 20804306)

1,105760429

(18,66772951)

0,670377898

(12,72379956)

0,883600861

S/M

0,041641239

(3,431439058)

1,022977543

(12,37555906)

0,446043777

(5,21119817)

0,22609829

(2,969778499)

0,675645962

S/L

-0,027438155

(-2,630545954)

0,901872786

(12,69352835)

0,394267431

(5,359069075)

-0,484718105

(-7,407205096)

0,749372527

B/H

-0,023305672

(-2,055951654)

0,936508319

(12,06074673)

-0,915351385

(-11,69664684)

0,52133632

(7,47822124)

0,779093467

B/M

0,019747364

(3,063488685)

1,017256015

(23,16773054)

-0,051547321

(-1,133758889)

0,116994378

(2,892985604)

0,842384274

B/L

-0,026154182

(-3,659937512)

0,859075715

(17,64859175)

-0,1341081

(-2,660694431)

-0,268336922

(-5,985316244)

0,763655761

Risk-premium slope is near 1, however, in extreme cases S/H and B/L, the risk premium is lower than one. SMB coefficient is declining with size and has negative values for big stocks portfolios. HML coefficient decreases from high to low book-to-market ratio portfolios, and becomes negative for low stocks portfolios. The coefficient is in all six portfolios higher than in CAPM model and is quite high overall. Based on these results we can conclude that the three-factor model works better than the CAPM model.

Additional tests

I am also going to test if the factors are correlated between each other. If the existence of high and significant correlation will be proven, it will be the evidence of multicollinearity of the model. Here is the table of the correlations between factors:

Table 7. Correlation between factors

Factor

Risk-Premium

SMB

HML

Risk-Premium

1

SMB

0, 200436657

1

HML

-0,028943655

-0,222757321

1

The results show significant non-zero intercept in all portfolios. Almost all the coefficients are significant.

The correlation between the factors appears to be quite small, however, to check for autocorrelation it is a good idea to construct a Breusch-Godfrey test for each portfolio.

My arbitrary choice is to check for autocorrelation of order 4. The p-values of the tests are shown in the table below:

Table 8. Breusch-Godfrey test

Portfolio

Breusch-Godfrey p-value

S/H

0,116198395

S/M

0,143998994

S/L

0,643529957

B/H

0,172523473

B/M

0,181687137

B/L

0,520098893

Huge p-values are interpreted as not rejecting null hypothesis of no autocorrelation. So, in neither of the portfolios we find the evidence of autocorrelation. This is a very important result for the model. I am also going to check the model for heteroscedasticity by using Breusch-Pagan test. The p-values of the test for each portfolio are shown in the table below:

Table 9. Breusch-Pagan test

Portfolio

Breusch-Pagan p-value

S/H

3,53133E-05

S/M

9,39201E-05

S/L

0,026299407

B/H

4,49735E-06

B/M

0,212132957

B/L

1,59571E-05

There is significant evidence of heteroscedasticity in all six portfolios. So, we can construct the model with Newey-West standard errors to account for heteroscedasticity. The adjusted t-statistics are in the parentheses.

Table 10. Adjusted Statistics

Portfolio

Constant

Risk-Premium

SMB

HML

S/H

-0.036002

(-3.901838)

0.869970

(21.23354)

1.105760

(23.35617)

0.670378

(9.313049)

0.883601

S/M

0.041641

(2.523024)

1.022978

(13.04432)

0.446044

(5.552777)

0.226098

(1.964376)

0.675646

S/L

-0.027438

(-1.273740)

0.901873

(10.69828)

0.394267

(5.002529)

-0.484718

(-3.567074)

0.749373

B/H

-0.023306

(-0.770863)

0.936508

(7.183648)

-0.915351

(-15.27296)

0.521336

(2.613243)

0.779093

B/M

0.019747

(3.238125)

1.017256

(20.97366)

-0.051547

(-1.231641)

0.116994

(3.441950)

0.842384

B/L

-0.026154

(-4.863132)

0.859076

(19.57262)

-0.134108

(-3.630653)

-0.268337

(-6.677670)

0.770282

Now in two portfolios - S/L and B/H the intercept is insignificant, and in S/M portfolio the value factor becomes insignificant. All the other results are the same as in unstandardised errors models.

Four-factor Model

Now I will add the fourth factor to Fama-French model. The momentum factor was introduced by Carhart in 1997 but I will use the modification of this factor by Fama and French, which was published in 2012. Momentum is defined as the cumulative return of the stock in the previous eleven months. So, the momentum for my first observation period - January of 2008 will be the cumulative returns from February to December of 2007. Next for January of each year the stocks are grouped into three types - winners, neutral, and losers. The winners belong to stocks with top 30% momentum, the losers are the stocks with lowest 30% momentum, and the remaining stocks are considered neutral. The momentum factor is denoted as WML (winners minus losers) and each month is equal to the average between the difference of average returns between the small winner stocks and small loser stocks and the difference between average returns of big winner stocks and big loser stocks. Now the model has the following formula:

Size-B/M test

First, I am going to test the four-factor model on size-book-to-market portfolios, the same portfolios from the previous models. On the left-hand side we have the excess returns on each of the portfolios. Here are the statistics of the model:

Table 11. Four-factor model statistics

Portfolio

Constant

Risk-Premium

SMB

HML

WML

S/H

-0,025709005

(-3,010445279)

0,896965988

(16,30124777)

1,031861547

(17,09261377)

0,691467108

(13,6834538)

-0,14083911

(-3,428514522)

0,895524017

S/M

0,032202986

(2,524939888)

0,998223798

(12,14736878)

0,513804632

(5,698945319)

0, 206760747

(2,739691862)

0,12914104

(2,105020966)

0,689024298

S/L

-0,043221907

(-4, 202560129)

0,860476673

(12,985196)

0,507585072

(6,981687834)

-0,517056611

(-8,496241221)

0,215964778

(4,365461712)

0,788503932

B/H

-0,043605793

(-4,124781777)

0,863159216

(12,46801242)

-0,755230681

(-10,16466587)

0,488698604

(7,972478992)

0,275480791

(5,561386506)

0,832501385

B/M

0,021289337

(3,083003489)

1,021300152

(22,95433332)

-0,062617735

(-1,282775984)

0,120153645

(2,940543216)

-0,021098387

(-0,635182315)

0,842999255

B/L

-0,022263656

(-2,932367843)

0,869279412

(17,76972675)

-0,16203968

(-3,019151528)

-0,260365828

(-5,795416737)

-0,053232996

(-1,457605888)

0,774924932

The t-statistics are in the parentheses. The four-factor model yields some contradictory results. In two of the portfolios the momentum factor is not significant and does not improve the model. For small stocks the momentum factor is higher than for the big stocks. The value factor decreases with book-to-market ratio, which is the same result as in the three-factor model. The size factor is positive for the small stocks and negative for the big stocks, which replicates the previous results. The intercept and the risk-premium factor yield almost the same results as the three-factor model. Overall the average is equal to 80% compared to 78% in the three-factor model. The improvement in the model is quite subtle, however, there are no drawbacks of adding such a simple factor as momentum to the model. For further analysis we will check for autocorrelation and heteroscedasticity.

First, I will calculate simple correlation between the four factors:

Table 12. Correlation between factors

Factor

Risk-Premium

SMB

HML

WML

Risk-Premium

1

SMB

0, 200436657

1

HML

-0,028943655

-0,222757321

1

WML

0,058324087

-0,364516006

0, 192683282

1

The correlation between the momentum factor and the size factor is equal to - 0.36, which is quite a lot. This may lead to multicollinearity in the model. We should next check for autocorrelation in the model by constructing Breusch-Godfrey test. The arbitrary choice is to check for the autocorrelation of the fourth order. Here is the table with the Breusch-Godfrey p-values:

Table 13. Breusch-Godfrey test

Portfolio

Breusch-Godfrey p-value

S/H

0,543752369

S/M

0,08355782

S/L

0,06478932

B/H

0,082031181

B/M

0,133525053

B/L

0,318367273

In all six portfolios at 95% confidence level we do not reject the null hypothesis of zero autocorrelation of the fourth order. However, at 90% confidence level we reject this hypothesis in three portfolios, which did not happen in the three-factor model. The momentum factor is autocorrelative by its nature, and these results are not surprising. Luckily, at my basic confidence level of 95% there is no autocorrelation. Further I need to check whether there is heteroscedasticity in the four-factor model. I will construct Breusch-Pagan test for each portfolio:

Table 14. Breusch-Pagan test

Portfolio

Breusch-Pagan test p-value

S/H

6,4311E-06

S/M

1,16002E-06

S/L

0,000327393

B/H

4,76582E-07

B/M

0,170711702

B/L

3,04293E-07

In all six portfolios at 95% significance level we reject the null hypothesis of homoscedasticity. Hence, we need to account for heteroscedasticity by constructing Newey-West standard errors. Here are the statistics of the model, and t-statistics are in the parentheses.

Table 15. Adjusted Statistics

Portfolio

Constant

Risk-Premium

SMB

HML

WML

S/H

-0.025709

(-2.764178)

0.896966

(19.72104)

1.031862

(15.92382)

0.691467

(13.46946)

-0.140839

(-2.629897)

0.895524

S/M

0.032203

(1.839417)

0.998224

(16.01742)

0.513805

(6.739398)

0.206761

(2.066796)

0.129141

(1.725397)

0.689024

S/L

-0.043222

(-2.533850)

0.860477

(17.50086)

0.507585

(6.711670)

-0.517057

(-4.418647)

0.215965

(5.356969)

0.788504

B/H

-0.043606

(-1.922855)

0.863159

(12.77498)

-0.755231

(-13.14018)

0.488699

(3.007177)

0.275481

(6.293798)

0.832501

B/M

0.021289

(3.602939)

1.021300

(23.12504)

-0.062618

(-1.398652)

0.120154

(3.761099)

-0.021098

(-0.566316)

0.842999

B/L

-0.022264

(-3.062205)

0.869279

(16.30806)

-0.162040

(-3.122551)

-0.260366

(-6.747071)

-0.053233

(-0.915729)

0.774925

This model adds to the model with unstandardised errors the insignificance of momentum factor for S/M portfolio and the insignificance of the intercept for both S/M and B/H portfolios. All the other results and conclusions are the same.

Size-Momentum portfolios

Now we are going to group the portfolios into four groups by size and momentum factors. By size the stocks are broken down into small and big, and by momentum they are divided into winners and losers. We have four portfolios: small winners (S/W), small losers (S/L), big winners (B/W), and big losers (B/L). For the excess returns of each of the stocks we are going to construct the four-factor Fama-French model. The statistics are the following:

Table 16. Model Statistics

Portfolio

Constant

Risk-Premium

SMB

HML

WML

S/W

-0,00471071

(-0,445881108)

0,978979589

(14,38155037)

0,612173488

(8, 196883534)

0,037629442

(0,601920567)

0,478475515

(9,415201887)

0,800643099

S/L

-0,058658541

(-3,534242581)

0,668546589

(6,251671824)

0,942004287

(8,028964766)

0,233735601

(2,379954707)

-0,631688259

(-7,912343798)

0,71462696

B/W

-0,044991935

(-2,815408239)

0,748175365

(7,26623625)

-0, 199115593

(-1,76259916)

0,113492582

(1, 200198047)

0,38856699

(5,054868507)

0,498070212

B/L

0,003473122

(0,266709151)

1,033917368

(12,32262222)

-0,471145145

(-5,11816405)

-0,097660654

(-1,267407467)

-0,479377519

(-7,653019443)

0,650137711

The results are much worse for this kind of grouping than for the size-value portfolios.

R^2 for the big stocks is very low - it is equal for 0.498 for B/W portfolio and for 0.650 for B/L portfolio. In three out of four portfolios the value factor is not significant. This may mean that when we do not group the portfolios by book-to-market type, the value factor becomes irrelevant. We need to check for autocorrelation in the model by constructing Breusch-Godfrey test. I will again check for autocorrelation of the fourth order. The statistics of the test are the following:

Table 17. Breusch-Godfrey Statistics

Portfolio

Breusch-Godfrey p-value

S/W

0,771667085

S/L

1,14667E-07

B/W

0,000135313

B/L

0,137117674

Two of the portfolios - small losers and big winners show signs of autocorrelation. This result is not unexpected because momentum is autocorrelative by its nature. The stocks were group by their previous returns, so there is no surprise that the results are autocorrelated. Next we check the model for heteroscedasticity by applying Breusch-Pagan test. Test statistics are in the table below:

Table 18. Breusch-Pagan Statistics

Portfolio

Breusch-Pagan p-value

S/W

0.0042258

S/L

0.1009765

B/W

0.4022825

B/L

0.0123467

So, in two portfolios there is evidence of heteroscedasticity. Hence, we should use Newey-West standard errors to account for autocorrelation and heteroscedasticity in the model. After using Newey-West standard errors we get the following statistics (t-statistics are in the parentheses):

Table 19. Adjusted Statistics

Portfolio

Constant

Risk-Premium

SMB

HML

WML

S/W

-0.004711

(-0.354096)

0.978980

(15.96838)

0.612173

(7.405299)

0.037629

(0.480857)

0.478476

(7.662959)

0.800643

S/L

-0.058659

(-2.405469)

0.668547

(7.755168)

0.942004

(9.290363)

0.233736

(1.758057)

-0.631688

(-9.647446)

0.714627

B/W

-0.044992

(-1.862283)

0.748175

(6.921800)

-0.199116

(-1.634097)

0.113493

(1.005901)

0.388567

(5.849035)

0.498070

B/L

0.0034731

(0.209755)

1.0339173

(15.84188)

-0.471145

(-4.792960)

-0.097661

(-1.453550)

-0.479378

(-4.550365)

0.650138

After adjusting for autocorrelation and heteroscedasticity it is clear, that the model works badly. The value factor is insignificant in all four portfolios. For small stocks the size factor has a positive slope, while for the big stocks it in negative. For loser stocks the size effect is higher than for the winner stocks. Momentum factor is positive for the winner stocks and negative for the loser stocks. Overall, for Russian stock market the four-factor model should not be applied for size-momentum portfolios because of autocorrelation, heteroscedasticity and poor explaining power of the model.

A five-factor model

Factors definitions

Now I am going to add to the three-factor model two factors, which were mentioned in Fama and French 2015 paper “Five-factor asset pricing model”. These factors are profitability and investment. Profitability is defined as revenues minus costs of goods sold minus selling, general, administrative and interest expenses all divided by book equity of the company. For year t these number are taken from the year t-1. Top 30% stocks with high profitability are called robust and lowest 30% are called weak. So, profitability factor is called RMW and each month is defined as the difference between average returns of the robust stocks and the average returns of the weak stocks. The stocks are regrouped each year.

To calculate the company's investment we take the change in total assets in year t-1 compared to year t-2, all divided by total assets of the year t-2. Then all the stocks are grouped. Top 30% stocks are called aggressive and the lowest 30% are called conservative. Investment factor, CMA, is defined as the difference between average monthly returns of conservative stocks and average monthly returns of the aggressive stocks.

Now we have the following model:

Where ,

Size-B/M portfolios

Now I will estimate the five-factor model for each of the six size-value portfolios. The statistics of the models are in a table below, t-statistics are in the parentheses:

Table 20. Model statistics

Portfolio

Constant

Risk-Premium

SMB

HML

RMW

CMA

S/H

-0.019566

(-2.269001)

0.905280

(16.96136)

1.130024

(20.26169)

0.625700

(12.67032)

-0.238594

(-4.598614)

-0.014603

(-0.351367)

0.903589

S/M

0.010851

(0.937719)

0.957721

(13.37261)

0.399624

(5.339966)

0.309374

(4.668787)

0.444703

(6.387593)

0.022692

(0.406901)

0.768338

S/L

-0.019561

(-1.725861)

0.889104

(12.67419)

0.437969

(5.974774)

-0.492035

(-7.580663)

-0.038620

(-0.566332)

0.148117

(2.711503)

0.767534

B/H

-0.045715

(-3.468841)

0.858133

(11.47043)

-0.927532

(-12.31274)

0.560192

(8.540630)

0.288223

(3.643015)

0.105119

(1.917482)

0.812867

B/M

0.022734

(3.170670)

1.012222

(22.80943)

-0.034771

(-0.749833)

0.114313

(2.784050)

-0.014147

(-0.327934)

0.057163

(1.654211)

0.846814

B/L

-0.029613

(-3.701785)

0.860154

(17.37243)

-0.148405

(-2.868426)

-0.262974

(-5.740391)

0.028509

(0.592316)

-0.041377

(-1.073214)

0.773861

The investment factor is insignificant in five portfolios, and the profitability factor is insignificant in three portfolios. on average increases only by 1% compared to the four-factor model. It is likely that the value factor is highly correlated with profitability and investment and absorbs all the effects from these two factors. We need to check for the correlation between the regressors. Here is the table:

Table 21. Correlation between factors

Factor

Risk-Premium

SMB

HML

RMW

CMA

Risk-Premium

1

SMB

0, 200436657

1

HML

-0,028943655

-0,222757321

1

WML

0,162967073

0,182753559

-0,225012039

1

CMA

0,055350339

-0,186636275

0,043551443

-0,096571649

1

There is no evidence of high correlation between the regressors, but the next step is to check for serial autocorrelation by constructing Breusch-Godfrey test (for the fourth order):

Table 22. Breusch-Godfrey Statistics

Portfolio

BG p-value

S/H

0.8082

S/M

0.1691

S/L

0.2428

B/H

0.0730

B/M

0.2052

B/L

0.6055

There is evidence of autocorrelation in all six portfolios. To fix this problem we can use Newey-West standard errors and see if profitability and investment become significant:

Table 23. Adjusted Statistics

Portfolio

Constant

Risk-Premium

SMB

HML

RMW

CMA

S/H

-0.019566

(-3.081661)

0.905280

(21.25940)

1.130024

(25.91554)

0.625700

(14.29381)

-0.238594

(-5.192705)

-0.014603

(-0.341709)

0.903589

S/M

0.010851

(0.743399)

0.957721

(13.46993)

0.399624

(5.938524)

0.309374

(5.815076)

0.444703

(5.035359)

0.022692

(0.333523)

0.768338

S/L

-0.019561

(-0.878268)

0.889104

(9.846237)

0.437969

(5.357277)

-0.492035

(-3.530856)

-0.038620

(-0.557166)

0.148117

(2.665018)

0.767534

B/H

-0.045715

(-1.659387)

0.858133

(7.529904)

-0.927532

(-14.38091)

0.560192

(3.504896)

0.288223

(3.570261)

0.105119

(1.690053)

0.812867

B/M

0.022734

(3.398103)

1.012222

(22.22251)

-0.034771

(-0.846435)

0.114313

(3.408071)

-0.014147

(-0.341171)

0.057163

(1.677961)

0.846814

B/L

-0.029613

(-4.765759)

0.860154

(21.07871)

-0.148405

(-3.597788)

-0.262974

(-6.032794)

0.028509

(0.585317)

-0.041377

(-0.939912)

0.773861

Again, investment is insignificant in five portfolios and profitability is insignificant in three portfolios. The model still works poorly. I see two possible ways to improve the model: to regroup the stocks and to exclude the value factor from the model. We can group the portfolios by size/profitability and size/investment. I shall start from size/profitability.

Size-profitability portfolios

There are two possible sizes - big and small, and three possible profitability types - robust, neutral and weak. So, there are six portfolios - S/W, S/N, S/R, B/W, B/N, B/R. I will construct the five-factor model for excess returns on each of these portfolios. Here are the statistics of the models:

Table 24. Model Statistics

Portfolio

Constant

Risk-Premium

SMB

HML

RMW

CMA

S/W

0.035914

(1.637824)

0.908859

(14.87011)

0.908653

(8.111488)

0.406189

(2.614095)

-1.004187

(-11.20749)

-0.041895

(-0.640489)

0.787344

S/N

-0.004748

(-0.210457)

0.960088

(8.259957)

0.260898

(2.245199)

-0.048109

(-0.488178)

0.122015

(1.208692)

0.068722

(1.200065)

0.640552

S/R

0.004614

(0.350289)

1.057487

(16.50266)

0.493528

(6.899234)

0.190139

(2.282912)

0.531983

(7.749688)

0.048481

(0.899989)

0.880267

B/W

-0.050126

(-3.193486)

0.955456

(15.50376)

-0.606949

(-6.049975)

-0.090842

(-1.157689)

-0.158552

(-2.424365)

0.102705

(2.220551)

0.770205

B/N

0.006679

(0.776118)

0.918746

(20.91827)

-0.066888

(-1.749806)

0.013764

(0.300685)

-0.047297

(-1.213573)

0.007956

(0.196630)

0.805211

B/R

-0.018826

(-2.339073)

0.806828

(12.92673)

-0.191824

(-2.782618)

0.125208

(1.661426)

0.305277

(3.270344)

0.012328

(0.264651)

0.697816

I build Newey-West standard residuals, and the t-statistics are in the parentheses. Again, in five out of six portfolios investment factor is insignificant. The average R is equal to 0.76 and is lower than in four-factor model. The change in grouping did not improve the results.

Size-investment portfolios

Now I form four portfolios according to size and investment types - small, big, conservative and aggressive. We get four combinations - S/C, B/C, S/A and B/A. We are building the five-factor model for excess monthly returns for each of these four portfolios. Here are the statistics:

Table 25. Model Statistics

Portfolio

Constant

Risk-Premium

SMB

HML

RMW

CMA

S/C

0.077699

(4.185283)

1.081332

(15.08840)

0.919632

(7.968045)

0.434801

(3.066242)

-0.032914

(-0.341395)

0.536185

(5.784183)

0.786395

B/C

-0.106819

(-4.353855)

0.758866

(14.12229)

-0.912717

(-6.724116)

-0.142677

(-1.204321)

0.090437

(0.683918)

0.670799

(7.484723)

0.709900

S/A

-0.023708

(-1.219331)

0.987991

(12.60753)

0.214906

(1.992304)

0.157374

(2.168730)

-0.051095

(-0.504285)

-0.646435

(-6.388540)

0.710238

B/A

-0.005412

(-0.566300)

0.852207

(15.32243)

-0.207992

(-2.379688)

0.134751

(1.891615)

0.108618

(1.197730)

-0.146581

(-2.247753)

0.660669

I build Newey-West standard errors and the t-statistics are in the parentheses. Now, investment factor becomes significant, but the profitability factor and the value factor are insignificant. Moreover, the explaining power of the model decreases. These results are unsatisfactory, so I also tried to remove the value and profitability from the model. In neither case the results improved. Here I will stop my tests on the fixe factor model, because more detailed sorting will cause parsimony issues. Fama and French stated that the complicated sorting choice is arbitrary and not convenient to construct and interpret.russian market could be atypical in its inefficiency, and the five-factor model yields controversial results when tested on Russian stocks. Although some of the factors were proven to be insignificant, nevertheless the five-factor model improves the explaining power of the four-factor model by 1% on average and is equal from 0.76 to 0.90, which is quite high.

Common Patterns

Now the most important part of the paper is to find the common patterns and differences in the model, which would allow to make possible conclusions about asset pricing.

In the three factor model small stocks display positive size premiums, while big stocks have negative size premium, which is a contradictory result with original work of Fama and French (1992). The value factor premium decreases from stocks with high book-to-market ratio to stocks with low book-to-market ratio, and this result is in line with Fama and French conclusions. Low BE/ME stocks even have negative exposure to the value factor. The three-factor model has high explaining power - from 0.68 to 0.89 and beats CAPM model, which shows poor results. In extreme cases - small stocks with high BE/ME and big stocks with low BE/ME the three-factor model has a negative intercept.

When we build a four-factor model and group the stocks by size and value. The small stocks have a positive size premium, which declines from high book-to-market ratio to low. The big stocks have a negative size premium and its absolute value decreases from stocks with high book-to-market ratio to low. The value factor premium decreases from high book-to-market stocks to low for both big and small portfolios. Similar to the three-factor model, it is negative for the low book-to-market stocks. For fixed BE/ME ratio the value effect of the small stocks is bigger than for the big stocks. The momentum factor is insignificant in three portfolios - S/M, B/M, and B/L. In the remaining three portfolios its statistics are quite contradictory. For S/H portfolio momentum effect is negative, and for S/L and B/H portfolio it is positive. It is hard to find any pattern in these results as there are too much insignificant results. The intercept is significant in four portfolios and in three of them it is negative - including extreme cases of S/H stocks and B/L stocks. The explaining power of the four-factor is high and in fact on average improves the three-factor model explaining power by two percent. Its range is from 0.68 to 0.89.

If we group the stocks by size and momentum, then the four-factor model yields following results: again for the small stocks the size effect is positive and for big stocks it is negative. For loser stocks the size factor is bigger by absolute number. The value factor is insignificant for all four portfolios, which is surprising. This means that the value effect is absorbed by some other variable, which is probably momentum. Momentum factor now becomes significant in all four portfolios and displays a positive effect for the winner stocks and a negative effect for the loser stocks. This effect by absolute value is bigger for the small stocks than for the big ones. The explaining power of the model is much lower this time, its range is from 0.49 to 0.8. It means that the value effect is not fully absorbed by other effects. Neither it is captured by intercept - it is insignificant in three out of four portfolios.

When we build a five-factor model by adding profitability and investment factors to the three-factor model and group the stocks by size and value, we get the following results: the small stocks have positive size effect and the big stocks have a negative size effect. Fixing the value of the stocks, small stocks have a bigger size effect than big stocks. If we fix the size of a portfolio, high book-to-market stocks have a bigger size effect than low book-to-market stocks. The value factor displays the same pattern as before: in decreases from high BE/ME to low BE/ME stocks and it is negative for low BE/ME. For small stocks the value effect is again higher than for the big stocks. Profitability effect turns out to be insignificant for low BE/ME stocks and for B/M stocks. For the remaining three portfolios it does not show an apparent pattern. The profitability effect is negative for S/H stocks and it is positive for S/M and B/H stocks. The investment effect is significant in only one portfolio - S/L, where it is positive. The intercept is insignificant in three portfolios and is negative in the extreme cases of S/H and B/M stocks. Although there are many insignificant results in the model, its explaining power is really high - from 0.77 to 0.90 and on average it improves the four-factor model by one percent. So, five-factor model despite some issues with insignificance has a higher explaining power than the three - and four-factor models.

However, to find significance in profitability and investment I regrouped the stocks. First I grouped them by size and profitability. In this case the size effect is positive for small stocks and negative for big stocks. When we fix the profitability, the size premium for the small stocks is bigger by absolute value than for the big stocks. The value effect is insignificant in four out of six portfolios. The profitability factor is insignificant for the neutral profitability portfolios. The profitability effect is negative in the weak profit stocks and it is positive in the robust profit stocks. This result matches economic logic that the stocks of high profit companies have positive profitability effect and vice versa. As usual, the profitability effect is bigger for the small stocks than for the high stocks. The investment factor is significant in only one portfolio, so the regrouping did not help to catch the investment effect. The explaining power of the model is quite high, but on average it is lower than the three-and four-factor model and is equal to 0.76. It is still a good result, but this kind of grouping did not really bring any improvements to the model.


Подобные документы

  • Executive summary. Progect objectives. Keys to success. Progect opportunity. The analysis. Market segmentation. Competitors and competitive advantages. Target market segment strategy. Market trends and growth. The proposition. The business model.

    бизнес-план [2,0 M], добавлен 20.09.2008

  • Types of Firms. Advantages of sole proprietorships. Disadvantages of sole proprietorships. Disadvantages of partnerships. Advantages of partnerships. Types of Stock. Advantages of Corporations. Disadvantages of Corporations. Forming a Corporation.

    презентация [4,6 M], добавлен 29.11.2014

  • Software as a Service, a form of cloud computing service model of software users. SaaS subscription model: key features, market drivers and constraints. Impact of SaaS subscription services business in the economy and society in Russia and abroad.

    дипломная работа [483,8 K], добавлен 23.10.2016

  • Crisis in Russia and international tobacco enterprises. International tobacco companies in the Russian market. Рroper suggestions with the purpose to adapt them to the Russian tobacco market in the new circumstances to maintain the level of profit.

    реферат [15,4 K], добавлен 15.05.2016

  • Study of possible types of the special advertising and its value on the example of the use different firms in the different areas of management. Determination of features of the special advertising depending on geography of business and market structure.

    курсовая работа [28,4 K], добавлен 12.10.2010

  • The history of the company. Entering the market of pastas and the present position of the company. The problem of the company. The marketing research. The history of the market of pastas of Saint Petersburg and its present state.

    курсовая работа [28,2 K], добавлен 03.11.2003

  • Порядок проведения рекламной кампании продукции. Учет особенностей человеческой психики при создании рекламы. Анализ модели восприятия рекламы - AIDMA model (внимание – интерес – желание – мотив – действие). Этапы процесса маркетинговых исследований.

    презентация [170,4 K], добавлен 02.06.2012

  • Business plans are an important test of clarity of thinking and clarity of the business. Reasons for writing a business plan. Market trends and the market niche for product. Business concept, market analysis. Company organization, financial plan.

    реферат [59,4 K], добавлен 15.09.2012

  • The current status of our business. Products and services. Benefits of location and challenges. Number of patients who received dental services in 2013. Impact from industry changes. Market description and characteristics. Market niche and share.

    бизнес-план [302,5 K], добавлен 02.10.2014

  • The main objectives promotion as the process. Overview and the Unique Aspects of Financial Services Industry. Financial Services, Customer Trust and Loyalty, Relationship Building. Aims of the DRIP elements as a "communication flow" model of promotion.

    курсовая работа [119,9 K], добавлен 25.04.2015

Работы в архивах красиво оформлены согласно требованиям ВУЗов и содержат рисунки, диаграммы, формулы и т.д.
PPT, PPTX и PDF-файлы представлены только в архивах.
Рекомендуем скачать работу.