The determinants of leveraged buyout activity

Leveraged buyout transactions: definition and core characteristics. Valuation techniques in leveraged buyout transactions. Hypothesis of leveraged buyout activity. Determinants of LBO activity. Empirical research: sample and data selection, methodology.

Ðóáðèêà Ôèíàíñû, äåíüãè è íàëîãè
Âèä ìàãèñòåðñêàÿ ðàáîòà
ßçûê àíãëèéñêèé
Äàòà äîáàâëåíèÿ 30.09.2016
Ðàçìåð ôàéëà 1,3 M

Îòïðàâèòü ñâîþ õîðîøóþ ðàáîòó â áàçó çíàíèé ïðîñòî. Èñïîëüçóéòå ôîðìó, ðàñïîëîæåííóþ íèæå

Ñòóäåíòû, àñïèðàíòû, ìîëîäûå ó÷åíûå, èñïîëüçóþùèå áàçó çíàíèé â ñâîåé ó÷åáå è ðàáîòå, áóäóò âàì î÷åíü áëàãîäàðíû.

Source: Capital IQ, 2016

Secondly, according to information presented in Picture 4, we can conclude that during 2004 - 2015 years the dominant share of leveraged buyouts occurred in sectors that generally are the most sensitive to economic cycles. Indeed, 27.5 percent of deals occurred with Consumer Discretionary and Consumer Discretionary targets. We can assume that this consumption cyclicality might be the one of the pre-determinants of LBO activity. Moreover, significant portion of Informational Technology and Healthcare transactions in the sample (30.3%) indicates a technology-intensiveness of analyzed portfolio.

Picture 5. “Number of Deals by Transaction Ranges”

Source: Capital IQ, 2015

On the base on data provided we can conclude, that total transaction size does not obey to the normal distribution.

When it comes to most active investors in leveraged buyouts, five most active buyers might be highlighted, they are:

Table 7. “Most Active Buyers/Investors”

Company Name

Total transaction Size ($mm)

Number of transactions

TPG Capital, L.P.

25 971.77

4

Permira Advisers Ltd.

24 028.41

5

The Carlyle Group LP

22 824.27

6

Ardian

18 817.4

3

The Blackstone Group L.P.

18 447.5

-

It worth mentioning, that five most powerful buyers are in response of 66.5% of total deal value in examined sample. Leading private equity investment company “Thoma Bravo, LLC” known for its track record of successfully closed deals in technology sector (application, infrastructure software) accounts for $10bln in total transaction size (~ 5.8 % of total deal value).

If superficial sample analysis is concerned, following data might be provided:

Table 8. “LBO statistics”

Total deal value ($mm)

165 481.108

Average Deal Value

555.306

Average TEV/Revenue

5.43

Average TEV/EBITDA (%)

11.56

Average Month Prior Premium (%)

16.38

It worth mentioning, that intermediate sample containing 360 closed deals subsequently might be trimmed significantly. Firstly, not for all companies transparent financial data provided in open sources (Capita IQ, Thomson Reuters Eikon, Bloomberg). Indeed, chosen methodology (Cox's proportional hazard model) requires collecting explanatory variables for each period during company's public life - since year when company firstly broke into the public market (IPO transaction) to the leveraged buyout announcement date. Therefore, we have to delete from sample firms on which financial information is not available. This restriction on data transparency diminished the sample from 360 deals between 2004 and 2015 to 228 transactions.

Control sample

Due to the fact, that current study devotes to estimate the determinants of leveraged buyout targets, the comparison sample of the surviving companies required. Following the same strict rules in the process of control sample selection, we gathered 1837 unique public companies. Screening criteria presented below.

1. Transaction Primary Features - Public Offering, IPO. S&P Capital IQ database contains the information about 26 471 IPO announcements. Public offerings announced in Unites States covered since 1997.

2. Assuming that all companies from our buyout sample went public after January 1, 2003, we limit control sample to Initial Public Offerings occurred strictly after 2003. Furthermore, since all of LBOs sample targets went public before December 31, 2012, we limit comparison sample to IPOs undertaken strictly before 31.12.2012. As a result, we got 12 320 IPOs occurred between 01.01.2003 - 31.12.2015.

3. Restriction on geographic location of IPOs companies: US and Canada, European Developed Markets, decreases the size of intermediate sample to 5 465 observations.

4. Initial Public Offerings of financial related firms (banks, insurance, etc.) accounting for 1765 observations were also deleted to provide control/buyout samples comparability.

5. Companies participated in financial or strategic buyer acquisition in a role of a target (with a majority stake acquired) during their public life were also excluded from monitoring as well as companies that lost their publicly listed status before 31.12.2015. As a result, the size of intermediate control sample decreased from 3 590 to 1824 unique observations

The aggregate characteristics of provided sample described below.

Firstly, the number of initial public offerings is also unevenly distributed among regions. 1075 events occurred in United States and Canada region - 58.5% of control sample observations. In other words, ten “survival” companies in Europe account for 1.4 buyouts, while buyout activity in North America is more intensive- ten “survival” firms account for 2.3 LBOs.

Picture 6. “Number of LBOs by Sector”

According to information presented in Picture 6, we can conclude that IPO activity is uniformly distributed among Industrials, Consumer Discretionary, Healthcare and Information Technology. Whereas, special attention should be paid to the difference in Materials observations' share in control (22.8%) and in buyout (0.08) samples. In general, ten “survival” companies (form all industries except Materials) account for 2.3 buyouts, while Materials companies are less at risk of being leveraged buyout candidate - ten “survival” firms account for 0.7 LBOs.

It is worth noting, intermediate comparison sample containing 1824 companies (carried out a public offering between 01.01.2003 - 31.12.2012 and still stay public without a track record of being targeted in transactions with > 50% acquired stake) was trimmed significantly due to restrictions on data availability to 1435 observations.

3.2 Methodology: cox proportional hazard model

Some dependent variables in economy as a whole and in a company' life cycle in particular come in a form of a duration. Modern duration analysis is considered to be the core instrument available to scientists studying “survival cases” such as examining the length of time before a former prisoner is arrested for a crime again or testing the number of weeks unemployed, etc.

Moreover, when the probability of exiting the original state within a short time period is concerned, duration analysis tends to focus on hazard functions implementation. For that reason, the company's decision to make leveraged buyout transformation is a “classical” case for the Cox's proportional hazard model analysis.

Supposing, that is a length of time company é being public in year ?, measured in years. Than is roughly the probability that the IPO firm decide to make LBO transformation during the year, conditional on not having done so until that point of time.

Proportional hazard model can be written as:

ü is called a baseline hazard, representing average rate at which public companies decide to make LBO transformation over their public life cycle. In other words, baseline hazard is common to all companies in the estimated sample regardless of the firm's specific characteristics.

ü is a vector of explanatory proxies. Explanatory variables are gathered for each period during company's “public life”. In case of companies from private sample - for each year since IPO closed to buyout announcement. In case of firms from control sample - for each year since IPO closed to 31.12.2015. It worth mentioning, that in order to reduce endogeneity problem all explanatory proxies are lagged by one period (year).

As a result, Cox proportional hazard model traces the evolution of determinants over company's life cycle (since IPOs to leveraged buyout announcement or censored).

In the following part of current research, we are going to present basic hazard model that is suitable to test hypothesis provided earlier. In order to do so, the list of dependent variables required.

3.3 Data overview

Explanatory measures for “asymmetric information” hypothesis

There is a clear link between product market characteristics and the decision of making leveraged buyout transformation - a sort of trade-off between cost and benefits of information disclosure. Indeed, public market requires the high level of transparency - strategy, financials, operational efficiency metrics as well as product portfolio characteristics should be reported on a regular basis. Firms with innovative technology profile usually suffers from disclosure procedures: fostered by expectations of short-term investor, listed companies compelled to chase for quarterly profits instead of focus on innovation activity. Moreover, the complete transparency of business processes may stimulate product market rivals to copy company's innovations. Furthermore, due to the underdevelopment of intellectual property market, the cost of information is very high. In other words, it is difficult to distinguish “lemons from peaches” among technology companies, what leads to high volatility and undervaluation. For example, one sound clinical trial failure may stimulate a knock on effect on the biotech market as a whole.

On the contrary, private equity managers - specialists in different sub-sectors of technology industry, are able to overcome this information asymmetry, catch “peach”, make it private via leveraged buyout transformation and focus primary on value creation through long term growth. Fortunately, low interest rates as well as steadily development of credit instruments (intellectual property collateralization) and great amount of “dry power” on private equity markets enables buyout managers to attract necessary funds for quite risky but potentially high profitable technology investments.

As a result, we expect that there is a clear link between a rich intellectual property profile of a target company and the decision to make leveraged buyout transformation.

Hypothesis 1: there is a clear link between a rich intellectual property profile of a target company and the decision to make leveraged buyout transformation

In order to test this hypothesis, we chose following metric for firms' innovation activity (presented in a tabular form).

Table 9. “Innovation activity proxies”

¹

Variable name ()

Proxy

Description

Expected Sign

1

R&D ratio

rd_assets

R&D Expense ? Total Assets

+

2

R&D dummy

rd_dum

1, if R&D =0

//-//-//

3

Intangible Assets ratio

int_ta

Book Value of Intangible Assets /Book Value of Total assets

+

4

Tangible Book Value to Price

tbv_cap

Market Cap/ Tangible BV

+

5

Tangible Book Value dummy

tbv_dum

1, if TBV<0

6

Hard Assets ratio

nppe_ta

Net PPE/ Total Assets

-

7

CIV ratio

civ_ebit

CIV premium/ EBIT

+

8

CIV dummy

Civ_dum

1, if firm's ROAt < Industry ROA

//-//-//

9

KCE ratio

kce_gp

=KCE premium/Operating income

+

9

KCE dummy

kce_dum

1, if KCE premium < 0

+

Unfortunately, there is no strict unified requirements as for the R&D disclosure. Depending on the state of incorporation and corresponding legal restrictions, industry classification or definite stage of company's life cycle, requirements for disclosure vary. Therefore, we suppose that proxy “rd_assets” might be insignificant due to the lack of firm's comparability on R&D basis. In order to mitigate a potential insignificance, we introduced dummy variable for the observations with Research and Development expenses equals zero.

Intangible asset ratio is a widely used proxy for target's innovation activity estimation. According to Capital IQ classification, Total Intangibles classified into two class of assets: goodwill and other intangibles. Other intangibles (intangible assets plus capitalized or purchased software) are really difficult to identify, valuation process of intangibles is a challenge not only for an acquirer but also for a target itself. The same time, intangibles are the main value drivers.

Goodwill arises as a result of transactions in which company acts as an acquirer, buying target company with a significant premium - the difference between purchase price paid and target's fair value. Nowadays, owning to overheated financial markets, extreme market valuations as well as huge undistributed private equity's “dry power”, purchase price allocation to goodwill is significant as never before. KPMG - Audit, Tax, Advisory. “Intangible Assets and Goodwill in the context of Business Combinations” - 2010 On the one hand, large bidding premiums indicates optimistic synergy expectations, on the other - cause a risk of future impairment.

It worth mentioning, that under US GAAP requirements, intangible assets Other Intangibles in accordance to Capital IQ Classification are amortized (tax shield arise), while goodwill might be only written down in case of failing impairment test. For that reason, sophisticated IP valuations approaches required in order to allocate primary part of premium paid on intangibles rather than goodwill. Paul Pignataro. “Leveraged buyouts: a practical guide to investment banking and private equity”, Wiley Finance - 2013,, page 162 As a result, we expect proxy “int_ta” to have a positive sign.

Tangible Book Value to Price ratio is a valuation metric that estimates share of hard assets in company's market capitalization. In other words, TBV to Price ratio indicates to what extent market value of equity secured by firm's fixed assets. Relatively low “tbv_cap” ratio, ceteris paribus, characterize the growth potential of a company as well as its intellectual-intensive nature.

The next group of dummies devotes to intangible assets valuation, they are: CIV (Stewart) and KCE (Baruch Lev).According the first method, the difference between company's actual profit and the expected return on tangibles is attributed for sources, generated primarily by intangibles.

CIV premium = ((1 - Tax Rate) * (EBIT - (Industry Average ROA*Tangible Assets Value))

In order to calculate industry weighted average returns on Tangible assets for industry ÷ in year `t', following formula applied:

=

Firstly, we made Capital IQ screens of public companies, operating in US and European developed markets, for each industry sector. For each public company `é', related to industry `÷' data - EBIT, Total Tangible Assets, Market Capitalization - was gathered in yearly basis since 2003 to 2015. Further, annual ROA tang values were averaged.

Table 10. “Weighted average returns on tangible assets by industries, 2003-2015”

Energy

Consumer Discretion

Consumer Staples

Healthcare

Industrials

IT

Util.

Telecom

Materials

0.06

0.18

0.22

0.18

0.16

0.14

0.06

0.14

0.08

It worth mentioning, that CIV method is applicable only in cases when company's return on tangible assets exceed the industry average level. If company's return on tangible assets is lower than the industry average level - dummy “civ_dum” applied. Indeed, we expect CIV ratio to take positive link to leveraged buyout decision.

Alternative to CIV-to apply Knowledge Capital Earnings method, introduced by L. Baruch. According to KCE method, earnings should match assets that generate them. Baruch Lev estimated that on average, physical assets provide average annual after-tax return ~ 7%, while rate of return on financial assets ~ 4.5%. The remaining part of income is generated by intellectual capital.

KCE premium = Gross Profit ? Income Tax ? Physical Assets of Firms7% - Financial Assets of Firm4.5%

Physical assets = Net Property Plant & Equipment + Inventories

Financial assets = Long-Term Investments + Short-Term Investments + Cash& Cash Equivalents

The higher KCE ratio, the higher potion of income generated by intellectual property is. Consequently, we expect that KCE ratio will take positive link to leveraged buyout decision.

Pre-transaction Operating characteristics of target company.

Hypothesis 2: Likelihood for a firm to be a LBO target relates to pre-transaction Operating characteristics of this company.

Table 11. “Operational Measures”

¹

Variable name ()

Proxy

Description

Expected Sign

1

Revenues

log_rev

Log(sales)

-

2

Revenues Dummy

rev_dum

1, if Sales = 0

//-//-//

3

Tobin's Q

tbq

(Market Cap +BV Total Debt)/ BV Total Assets

-

4

Fixed Assets ratio

nppe_ta

Net PPE/ Total Assets

+

Unlevered Free Cash Flow ratio

fcf_ta

UNLEVERED_FCF/ Total Assets

+

Cash ratio

cash_ta

Cash/ Total assets

+

7

Debt Ratio

td_ta

Total Debt/ Total assets

-

8

Capex ratio

capex_ta

Capex/ Total assets

+/-

As it was mentioned earlier, classical leveraged buyout literature put an emphasis on the estimation of agency conflict theory. Authors suppose that managers of mature companies, generating stable cash flows, tend to invest available cash in project with negative present value. Since then, leveraged buyout market evolved, but high FCFF levels, strong cash position, relatively low Capex requirements and pre-transaction debt levels - are those criteria that attracts buyout investors, even technology focused ones.

Hypothesis 3: Likelihood for a firm to be a LBO target relates to pre-transaction performance of this company on financial markets.

Table 12.“Financial metrics”

Variable name ()

Proxy

Description

Expected Sign

Capital Access

Number of firms acquired

f_aquir

Number of transactions in which target firm was an acquirer during a year

-

No firms acquired dummy

no_firms_dum

1, if company did not acquire any company during a year

+

Dividends Dummy

div_dum

1, if company paid dividends during a year

-

Stock Market Performance

Price Volatility

p_vol

1Year price volatility

+

Stock Price return

s_ret

1 Year stock return adjusted on S&P Index

-

Turnover

turn

Stock Turnover = Volume of shares traded/ Shares Outstanding

-

Financial Visibility

Institutional Ownership

inst_own

% of Institutional investors (target's owners)

-

Institutional Ownership dummy

inst_own_dum

1, if company did not disclosure its ownership structure

//-//-//

Strategic Ownership

strat_own

% of Institutional investors (target's owners)

+

Strategic Ownership dummy

strat_own_dum

1, if company did not disclosure its ownership structure

//-//-//

VC_PE Ownership

vcpe_own

% of Institutional investors (target's owners)

-

VC_PE Ownership dummy

vcpe_own_dum

1, if company did not disclosure its ownership structure

//-//-//

Banks Ownership

bank_own

% of Institutional investors (target's owners)

-

Banks

Ownership dummy

bank_own_dum

1, if company did not disclosure its ownership structure

//-//-//

We expect that that the easier the capital access of a public company is, the less likely the firm will decide to opt out the public market via leveraged buyout. Consequently, we expect that there is a negative link between firm's active behavior on financial markets (successfully conducted acquisitions, sound track record of dividend payments) and the decision to undertake leveraged buyout transformation. Moreover, the more stable stock market performance (in term of volatility, returns and turnover) the lower the need to attract private equity managers. Furthermore, financially healthy companies with satisfactory analyst following surely cause an interest among institutional investors, private equity funds and investment banks. These companies are less likely to be involved in change in control transactions such as leveraged buyouts. On the contrarily, firms with concentrated ownership primarily in hands of insiders (managers, CEO, etc.), or other strategic investors are more at risk of leveraged buyout.

Hypothesis 4: Leveraged Buyout activity is driven by Economy-Wide factors.

Table 13. “Economy-Wide factors”

¹

Variable name ()

Proxy

Description

Expected Sign

1

Term Premium

term_prem

Yield Spread difference between 10 years and 2-year Treasury Bonds Ïðèëîæåíèå X

-

2

Equity Premium

eq_premium

Equity risk premium http://pages.stern.nyu.edu/~adamodar/

-

3

Libor rate

libor_rate

LIBOR (London Interbank Offered Rate)

-

4

GDP growth

gdp_growth

Annual US GDP Growth

+

Modern academic literature states that LBO activity positively relates to risk-free rate, supply of bank loans, CDOs market volumes, GDP growth rates and negatively correlates with market risk premiums and LIBOR rate.

IV. Empirical results

As it was stated earlier current research is devoted to compare company's characteristics among two samples. The final buyout sample includes 228 closed deals in which a listed company became a buyout target (LBO, MBO, Going Private) between 2004-2015 years. Moreover, research focuses primarily on targets that went public after January 1, 2003. The comparison sample contains 1435 companies, that carried out a public offering between 01.01.2003 - 31.12.2012 and still stay public without a track record of being targeted in transactions with > 50% acquired stake.

All hypothesis discussed at previous chapter were tested by Cox Proportional Hazard Model. The aim of the study is not only to test all hypothesis, but also to generate specification with primarily significant variables and high explanatory power.

Firstly, all explanatory variables were put in one hazard regression. As a result, Table 1 from Appendix was generated. As we can mention, that regression results revealed insignificants of great variety of variables. This is no surprising, as there are tens of variables in the regression model. Further, the following procedure was undertaken - we caught the less “interesting for research” variable, excluded it from the list and repeated the regression. In a result of such manipulations, the final specification arose. (Appendix 3, Table ¹ 2)

As we can see from the table, hazard regression managed to proof some hypothesis.

Firstly, there is a clear link between a rich intellectual property profile of a target company and the decision to make leveraged buyout transformation. This hypothesis confirmed by significant positive sigh of “int_ta” and “kce_gp” variables. On the base of findings provided we can conclude, that private equity managers, leveraging their wide network of contacts throughout the global technology and finance sector, don't afraid to acquire a “lemon”, on the contrary, they break into such deals are able to reduce capital market imperfections and enhance the efficiency of intangible assets utilization. The practical proof of idea illustrated in KPNG research, devoted to estimation the purchase price allocation in acquisition transactions (Appendix 1, Graph 14-15)

Secondly, regression revealed that, likelihood for a firm to be a LBO target relates to pre-transaction operating characteristics of this company. We see that targets with zero revenues, are less likely to become LBO targets. Whereas, firms with strong free cash flow position as well as significant fixed asset share are a good candidates for leveraged buyout transformation. Certainly, not each intellectual-property intensive company suits for LBO transformation. Indeed, only those who are able to produce strong predictable cash flows as well as lucrative growth prospects can count for a deal.

On the base of regression findings, we can conclude that financial visibility hypothesis is proven on the estimated samples. Indeed, another group of determinant, designed to disclose the relationship between success in target's stock performance and the likelihood of leveraged buyout transformation, also obtained an empiric proof. To begin with, there is a strong positive relation between stock volatility and probability of going private, what is in line with financial visibility theory. In other words, private equity funds more likely seek for candidates that have failed to show stable track -record of market performance. Indeed, high volatile firms with lower returns may also lack securitized analysts, what leads to illiquidity of shares, rise in the degree of undervaluation and excess in transaction costs (related to stock market listing). Furthermore, our regression supports these expectations - negative correlation between stock turnover and issuer decision to opt out of public markets through LBO.

According to regression results, IPO companies that have worse access to capital markets are more likely to perform leveraged buyout transformation. Otherwise, companies that have a rich history of successfully conducted secondary public offerings and wide experience in merger and acquisition transactions (in role of acquirer) are less likely to suffer from limited access to capital markets and therefore are less likely to go private through LBO.

The regression did not proof the assumption about prevalence of strategic investors on institutional ones in LBO Deals. On the contrary, there is a significant positive link between institutional ownership as well as vc_pe holdings and the decision to make LBO transformation. This can be explained by the fact, that before breaking into leveraged buyout and acquiring a majority stake, these investors “try” target company, by buying minority stake. The minority rights allow investors to require complex financial disclosure, and on the base of this data decide whether to conduct bigger deal or not.

Moreover, regression confirmed that LBO activity positively relates to GDP growth rates and negatively correlates with market risk premiums.

Conclusion

Current article provides a deep analysis of scientific studies devoted to the determinants of leveraged buyout activity estimation as well as sophisticated econometric modeling. On the base of this findings, new hypothesis were shaped and tested.

According to scrutinized analysis completed we can conclude, that the main focus of literature devoted to the first LBO boom (1980-1990) was on the pre-transaction “operating” characteristics of the target company. In fact, agency and information asymmetries theories were core in explaining leveraged buyout transformation. In turn, some common pre-transaction operating characteristics of LBO firms might be traced through academic studies, they are: hard assets, steady cash flows, low capital requirements, diversity, low Market-book ratio of target company.

The second LBO wave (2001-2007) was accompanied by sharp surge in trade volumes on financial markets along with increased quality of corporate governance. Due to the presence of information asymmetry not all young listed firms succeeded in attracting and holding analysts' attention and whereby lost their stock market positions. According to financial visibility hypothesis, namely these “looser' companies became core candidates for leveraged buyout transformation in the second surge of LBO activity.

Moreover, that modern academic literature states that LBO activity positively relates to risk-free rate, supply of bank loans, CDOs market volumes, GDP growth rates and negatively correlates with market risk premiums.

The sound shift in leveraged buyout philosophy occurred recently. This shift changed the negative perception of intellectual property based candidates over the recent years. “A new wave of tech buyouts has begun - one in which smaller firms with less-developed products are being taken private with large amounts of debt and relatively scant equity” Greg Miller. “The new trend ripping through the tech sector”, Wall Street Daily, LLC. - February 2015.

As long as literature review of articles on the issue was completed, research methods were structured, the most appropriate methodology for estimation LBO activity had been figured out, endogenous and exogenous determinants of leveraged buyout activity were defined and lastly, the process of sample selection begun, the econometric model was designed.

The regression result reveals the clear link between a rich intellectual property profile of a target company and the decision to make leveraged buyout transformation. Moreover, not each intellectual-property intensive company suits for LBO transformation. Indeed, only those who are able to produce strong predictable cash flows as well as lucrative growth prospects can count for a deal. Furthermore, financial visibility problems also may push target for LBO transformation.

References

1. Achleitner Ann-Kristin, Braun R., Hinterramskogler B. «Structure and Determinants of Financial Covenants in Leveraged Buyouts», Review of Finance (2012) 16: 647-684

2. Anjanette Raymond. “Intellectual Property as Collateral in Secured Transactions: Collision of Divergent Approaches”, University of London, http://ssrn.com/abstract=2019612

3. Anne-Laure Le Nadant, Frederic Perdreau. “Ex-Post Innovation Prof le of LBO Targets: Evidence from CIS Data for the Netherlands”, Published online in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com) DOI: 10.1002/jsc.1962 - (2014), pp. 93-105

4. Anne-Laure Le Nadant, Frederic Perdreau. “LBOs and innovation: the French case”, Author manuscript, Bodo - 2011

5. Anne-Laure Le Nadant, Frederic Perdreau. “LBOs' effects on innovation: evidence from France”, Transeo - 2013

6. Anne-Laure Le Nadant, Frederic Perdreau. «Financial Profile of Leveraged Buy-out targets: some French evidence», Review of Accounting and Finance, 2006, vol. 5, issue 4, pages 370 - 392

7. Anthony Wall, Robert Kirk, Gary Martin. “Intellectual Capital, Measuring the Immeasurable?”, CIMA Publishing - 2004, 111 pages. ISBN 0 7506 6171 2

8. Aswath Damodaran. “Investment valuation: second edition”, Wiley Finance - 2002, 1372 pages

9. Aswath Damodaran. “The Anatomy of an LBO: Leverage, Control, and Value”, CFA Institute - 2008, 28 pages

10. Axelson Ulf, Jenkinson T., Per Stromberg and Michael S. Weisbach. «Borrow Cheap, Buy High? The Determinants of Leverage and Pricing in Buyouts», The Journal of Finance, Vol. LXVIII, NO.6, December 2013

11. Baruch Lev. «Intangibles: Management, Measurement, and Reporting», Brookings Institution Press, Washington, D.C. - 2001, 133 pages

12. Bharath T., Amy K. Dittmar. «Why do firms use private equity to opt out of public markets», The Review of Financial Studies, Vol 23, ¹5, 2010

13. Boot Arnoud W.A., Anjan V. Thakor, Radhakrishnan Gopalan. «Market Liquidity, Investor Participation and Managerial Autonomy: Why Do Firms Go Private?», ECGI Finance Working Paper No. 119/2006

14. Boucly Q, D. A. Sraer, D. Thesmar. «Growth LBOs», Journal of Financial Economics (JFE), Forthcoming, November 01, 2011

15. Brealey Meyers. “Principles of Corporate Finance”, The McGraw?Hill Companies - 2003, 1061 pages

16. Brinkhuis S., Wouter De Maeseneire. «What Drives Leverage in Leveraged Buyouts? An Analysis of European LBOs' Capital Structure», Accounting&Finance, Vol. 52, pp. 155-182, 2012

17. Bruce W. Burton, Emma Bienias, Candice K. Quinn. “Financing Alternatives for Companies: Using Intellectual Property as Collateral”, Stout Risius Ross - 2014

18. Bruce W. Burton, Scott Weingust. “Why Private Equity and Venture Capital Firms Should Care About Intellectual Property Assets”, Stout Risius Ross - 2012

19. Cao J., Douglas J. Cumming, Meijun Qian, Xiaoming Wang. «Creditor Rights and LBOs», 5th Annual conference on Empirical Legal Studies Paper, February 15, 2010

20. CFA Institute. “Alternative investment and fixed income”, CFA Program curriculum 2015, level 2, volume 5 - 2014, 589 pages

21. Code of Federal Regulations, Title 12, “Banks and Banking”, PT. 220-299, Revised as of January 2010 - Office of the Federal register (US), Government Printing Office, 2010

22. Colla Paolo, F. Ippolito, Hannes F. Wagner. «Leverage and Pricing of Debt in LBOs», Journal of Corporate Finnace, Forthcoming

23. Cyril Demaria. “Introduction to private equity: venture, growth, LBO & turn-around capital”, John Wiley and Sons, Ltd. - 2013, 392 pages. ISBN 978-1-118-57192-7

24. Damodaran Aswath. «The Anatomy of an LBO: leverage, control, value there are three components», New York University - stern School of Business, 22 Jul 2008

25. Damodaran online. http://pages.stern.nyu.edu/~adamodar/

26. Daniel Ferreira, Gustavo Manso, André C. Silva. “Incentives to Innovate and the Decision to Go Public or Private”, Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of The Society for Financial Studies - July 8, 2012

27. Danka Starovic. “Understanding corporate value: managing and reporting intellectual capital”, CIMA-2003, 27 pages

28. David Stowell. “An Introduction to Investment Banks, Hedge Funds, and Private Equity”, 2014

29. Demiroglu Cem, Christopher M. James. «The role of private equity group reputation in LBO financing», Journal of Financial Economics 96 (2010), 306-330

30. Edgerton Jesse. «Agency Problems in Public Firms: Evidence from Corporate Jets in Leveraged Buyouts», The Journal of Finance, Vol. LXVII, No.6, December 2012

31. Elisa Ughetto, “Assessing the contribution to innovation of private equity investors: A study on European buyouts”, Research Policy 39 (2010), pp. 126-140

32. Enrique R. Arzac “Valuation of Highly Leveraged Firms”, CFA Institute, Financial Analysts Journal - 1996

33. Fabio Bertonia, Frédéric Perdreaub, Anne-Laure Le Nadant. “The Effect of Leveraged Buyouts on Strategic Innovation and Innovation-Related Activities”, http://www.siecon.org/online/wp-content/uploads/2015/10/Bertoni.pdf - June 1, 2015

34. Ferreira D., Manso G., Andre C. Silva. «Incentives to Innovate and the Decision to Go Public or Private», The Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 27 (2014)

35. Florian Schock. “Private equity financing of technology firms: a literature review”, EBS Business School Research Paper No. 14-06 - 2013, 37 pages

36. Frontier Economics. “Exploring the impact of private equity on economic growth in Europe”, Frontier Economics Ltd, London - 2013, 57 pages

37. Global Private Equity Report 2016. Bain & Company, Inc. - 2016, 72 pages

38. Greg Miller. “The new trend ripping through the tech sector”, Wall Street Daily, LLC. - February 2015

39. Guo Shourin, Edith S. Hotchkiss and Weihong Song. «Do Buyouts (Still) Create Value?», The Journal of Finance, Vol. 66, No 2 (April 2011), pp. 479-517

40. H. Mehran, S. Peristiani. «Financial Visibility and the Decision to Go Private», The Review of Financial studies, Vol. 23, ¹ 2 (Feb.,2010), pp. 519-547

41. Haddad V., Loualiche E. Matthew C. Plosser. «Buyout Activity: The Impact of Aggregate Discount Rates», Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Staff Report No. 606, March 2013

42. Halpern P., R. Kieschnick, W. Rotenberg, «On the Heterogeneity of Leveraged Going Private Transactions», The Review of Financial Studies, Vol.12, ¹2 (Summer,1999), pp. 281-309

43. Ivashina V., Kovner A. «The Private Equity Advantage: Leveraged Buyout Firms and Relationship Banking», The Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 24, No 7 (2011)

44. Jan Bena, Kai Li. “Corporate Innovations and Mergers and Acquisitions”, The journal of finance - vol LXIX, NO. 5 - October 2014, pp. 1923-1960

45. Jan Hofmann. “Value intangibles! Intangible capital can and must be valued - owners and valuers alike will benefit”, Deutsche Bank Research - October 2005

46. Jeffrey M. Wooldridge. «Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data», The MIT Press - 2003, 777 pages. ISBN: 0262232332

47. Jenkinson T., Rudiger Stucke. «Who benefits from leverage in LBOs?», University of Oxford - Said Business School, February 28, 2011

48. John Gilligan, Mike Wright “Private equity demystified - an explanatory guide”, ICAEW - 2014, 36 pages. ISBN 978-1-78363-168-1

49. Josh Lerner, Morten Sørensen, Per Strömberg. “Private Equity and Long-Run Investment: The Case of Innovation”, Harvard business school, Working Paper 09-075 - December 2008

50. Joshua Rosenbaum, Joshua Pearl. “Investing banking - Valuation, Leveraged buyouts and M&A”, Wiley Finance - 2013, 312 pages. ISBN 978-1-118-47220-0

51. Kaplan, S.N., 1989. «Management buyouts: evidence on taxes as a source of value», Journal of Finance 44, 611-632.

52. Kaplan, S.N., Per Stromberg. «Leveraged Buyouts and Private Equity», the Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 23, No 1(Winter, 2009), pp. 121-146

53. Kevin Amess, Joel Stiebale, Mike Wright. “The impact of private equity on firms' patenting activity”, European Economic Review, http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0014292115001300 - September 2015

54. KPMG - Audit, Tax, Advisory. “Intangible Assets and Goodwill in the context of Business Combinations” - 2010

55. Malenko A., Malenko N. «A theory of LBO activity based on repeated debt-equity conflicts», Journal of Financial Economics, forthcoming (April 2015)

56. Marais, Laurentius, 1989, «Wealth effects of going private for senior securities», Journal of Financial Economics 23, 155-191.

57. Nicole Torres. “Private Equity can make firms more innovative”, Harvard business review - 2015

58. Nikoskelainen Erkii. «The Operating Characteristics of Leveraged Buyouts: Empirical Evidence from Europe», Swedish School of Economics and Business Administration, LTA 3/06, p. 296-335

59. Opler T., Sheridan Titman, «Determinants of Leveraged Buyout Activity: Free Cash Flow vs. Financial Distress Costs», The journal of Finance , Vol. 48, ¹5 (Dec., 1993), pp. 1985 -1999

60. Paul Pignataro. “Leveraged buyouts: a practical guide to investment banking and private equity”, Wiley Finance - 2013, 321 pages. ISBN 978-1-118-47220-0

61. Private equity international. Annual review 2015, 80 pages

62. Private equity international. Issue 141 December 2015 / January 2016, 52 pages

63. Private equity international. Issue 142/ February 2016, 36 pages

64. Private equity international. Issue 143/ March 2016, 48 pages

65. Private equity international. Perspectives 2016, 44 pages

66. Renneboog, L. T. Simson. «Public-to-Private Transactions: LBOs, MBOs, MBIs and IBOs»// Center Discussed paper: Vol.2005-98. Tilburg: Finance

67. Robert A. Finkel, David Greising. “The masters private equity and venture capital”, The McGraw?Hill Companies - 2010, 308 pages. ISBN 978-0-07-162460-2

68. Roden M. Dianne, Wilbur G. Lewellen. «Corporate Capital Structure Decision: Evidence from leveraged Buyouts», Financial Management, Vol. 24, No. 2, Silver Anniversary Commemoration (Summer, 1995), pp. 76-87

69. Shai Bernstein. “Does Going Public Affect Innovation?”, The journal of finance - vol LXX, NO. 4 - August 2015, pp. 1365-1403

70. Shivdasani A., Yihui Wang. «Did Structured Credit Fuel the LBO Boom?», The Journal of Finance, Vol. 66, NO.4 (August 2011), pp. 1291- 1328

71. Sreedhar T. Bharath, Amy K. Dittmar. “Why Do Firms Use Private Equity to Opt Out of Public Markets?', The Review of Financial Studies / v 23 n 5 - 2010, pp. 1771-1818

72. Stanfield Jared. «How Does Syndication Influence Leveraged Buyout Success», Australian School of Business, July 5, 2014

73. Steven N. Kaplan, Per Strömberg. `'Leveraged Buyouts and Private Equity', Journal of Economie Perspectives, volume 23, Number 1 - Winter 2009, pp. 121-146

74. Sofat, Rajni, Hiro, Preeti Manual's examples: Strategic Financial management, Second Edition; PHI Leraning Pvt. Ltd.,2016, page 386

75. Tilman E. Pohlhausen. ”Technology Buyouts. Valuation, Market Screening Application, Opportunities in Europe”, Deutscher Universitats-Verlag GmbH, Wiesbaden - 2003, 108 pages. ISBN-13: 978-3-8244-7758-6

76. Wright M., Tomas Simons, Luc Renneboog. «Leveraged Public to Private Transactions in the UK», ECGI-Finance Working Paper No. 78/2005

Appendix 1

Graph 1. - “Total LBO volume borrowed by financial sponsors”

Source: Private equity international. Annual review 2015, page 28

Graph 2. - “Private equity fundraising 2010-15”

Source: Private equity international. Annual review 2015, page 36

Graph 3. -“Funds in market, 1 Jan 2015 - 1 Jan 2016”

Source: Private equity international. Annual review 2015, page 37

Graph 4. -“Co-investment funds closed 2010-15”

Source: Private equity international. Annual review 2015, page 44

Graph 5. -“Which three sectors are most likely to experience decreasing valuations in 2016?” Source: Private equity international. Issue 143/ March 2016, page 46

Graph 6. -“Debt to EBITDA levels in corporate LBOs”

Source: Private equity international. Issue 142/ February 2016, page 42

Graph 7. -“How significant are extreme market valuations? (by region)”

Source: Private equity international. Perspectives 2016, page 8

Graph 8. -“How significant is cheap debt pushing up prices? (by region)”

Source: Private equity international. Perspectives 2016, page 8

Graph 9. -“Annual senior loan LBO volume”

Source: Private equity international. Issue 141, December 2015 / January 2016, page 42

Graph 10. -“Average purchase price multiple of deals worth ˆ 500m or more are reaching their pre-crisis peak”

Source: Private equity international. Issue 141/ January 2016, page 42

Graph 11. -“Volume of leveraged deals in Europe”

Source: Private equity international. Issue 141 December 2015 / January 2016, page 43

Graph 12. -“Buyout leverage has been rising since 2009”

Source: Private equity international. Issue 141 December 2015 / January 2016, page 43

Graph 13. -“Debt as a proportion of buyout financing is still off pre-crisis levels” Source: Private equity international. Issue 141 December 2015 / January 2016, page 43

Graph 14. -“Percentage allocation of purchase price to goodwill by industry (Median)”. Source: KPMG - Audit, Tax, Advisory. “Intangible Assets and Goodwill in the context of Business Combinations”. 2010, page 11

Graph 15. -“Percentage allocation of purchase price to intangible assets by industry (Median)”

Source: KPMG - Audit, Tax, Advisory. “Intangible Assets and Goodwill in the context of Business Combinations”. 2010, page 15

Appendix 2

Table ¹1. “US 10Y Bonds, Annual Return”

Date

PX_LAST

PX_BID

31.12.2015

2,2694

2,2712

31.12.2014

2,1712

2,173

31.12.2013

3,0282

3,03

31.12.2012

1,7574

1,7591

30.12.2011

1,8762

1,8779

31.12.2010

3,2935

3,2974

31.12.2009

3,8368

3,8408

31.12.2008

2,2123

2,2156

31.12.2007

4,0232

4,027

29.12.2006

4,7022

4,702

30.12.2005

4,3911

4,391

31.12.2004

4,2182

4,218

31.12.2003

4,2455

4,246

Source: Bloomberg

Table ¹2. “US 2Y Bonds, Annual Return”

Date

PX_LAST

PX_BID

31.12.2015

1,0477

1,0517

31.12.2014

0,6645

0,6684

31.12.2013

0,3799

0,3838

31.12.2012

0,2468

0,2507

30.12.2011

0,2391

0,243

31.12.2010

0,5934

0,6013

31.12.2009

1,1354

1,1434

31.12.2008

0,7643

0,7722

31.12.2007

3,0466

3,0547

29.12.2006

4,808

4,8163

30.12.2005

4,3996

4,4079

31.12.2004

3,0651

3,0732

31.12.2003

1,8189

1,8269

Source: Bloomberg

Table ¹3 - “Twelve Month LIBOR Index”

Date

PX_ASK

31.12.2015

1,178

31.12.2014

0,6288

31.12.2013

0,5831

31.12.2012

0,8435

30.12.2011

1,12805

31.12.2010

0,78094

31.12.2009

0,98438

31.12.2008

2,00375

31.12.2007

4,22375

29.12.2006

5,32938

30.12.2005

4,83875

31.12.2004

3,1

31.12.2003

1,45688

Source: Bloomberg

Table ¹4 - “US Annual GDP, $mln”

Date

PX_ASK

31.12.2003

13271100

31.12.2004

13773475

31.12.2005

14234250

31.12.2006

14613800

31.12.2007

14873750

31.12.2008

14830375

31.12.2009

14418750

31.12.2010

14783800

31.12.2011

15020575

31.12.2012

15354625

31.12.2013

15583325

31.12.2014

15961650

31.12.2015

16348875

Source: Bloomberg

Appendix 3

Table ¹1 - “Summery Model 1”

. cloglog event `varlist' time time2

Iteration 0: log likelihood = -878.28884

Iteration 1: log likelihood = -877.03133

Iteration 2: log likelihood = -877.0288

Iteration 3: log likelihood = -877.0288

Complementary log-log regression Number of obs = 9548

Zero outcomes = 9320

Nonzero outcomes = 228

LR chi2(38) = 399.50

Log likelihood = -877.0288 Prob > chi2 = 0.0000

event | Coef. Std. Err. z P>|z| [95% Conf. Interval]

log_rev | -.0340283 .0513191 -0.66 0.507 -.1346119 .0665553

rev_dum | -1.601409 .7017262 -2.28 0.022 -2.976767 -.2260509

rd_assets | .7428967 .7770917 0.96 0.339 -.7801751 2.265969

rd_dum | .2180273 .1983793 1.10 0.272 -.1707889 .6068435

tbq | -.0445863 .0616884 -0.72 0.470 -.1654933 .0763207

int_ta | 1.569792 .4223504 3.72 0.000 .7420002 2.397584

tbv_dum | .1153103 .1949772 0.59 0.554 -.2668379 .4974585

tbv_cap | -.1533654 .0872279 -1.76 0.079 -.324329 .0175981

nppe_ta | 1.049245 .4713937 2.23 0.026 .1253306 1.97316

kce_gp | 1.22521 .6423335 1.91 0.056 -.0337408 2.48416

kce_dum | .5763405 .5975614 0.96 0.335 -.5948583 1.747539

fcf_ta | .32921 .172975 1.90 0.057 -.0098148 .6682347

td_ta | .0837126 .2516946 0.33 0.739 -.4095999 .577025

capex_ta | -1.009197 1.063781 -0.95 0.343 -3.094169 1.075775

cash_ta | -.9910392 .6801302 -1.46 0.145 -2.32407 .3419915

sga_rev | -.4113291 .2650607 -1.55 0.121 -.9308385 .1081803

sales_dum | -.3732906 .4969963 -0.75 0.453 -1.347386 .6008043

f_aquir | -.0506814 .0802546 -0.63 0.528 -.2079775 .1066148

no_firms_dum | .2243617 .2130686 1.05 0.292 -.1932452 .6419686

p_vol | .0033471 .0016785 1.99 0.046 .0000573 .0066369

s_ret | -1.458867 .1340118 -10.89 0.000 -1.721525 -1.196209

turn | -24.98293 15.9722 -1.56 0.118 -56.28788 6.322008

inst_own | .0096194 .0035585 2.70 0.007 .0026449 .0165939

inst_own_dum | .7265824 .227748 3.19 0.001 .2802045 1.17296

insider_own | .0080342 .0049015 1.64 0.101 -.0015727 .017641

insider_ow~m | .5092514 .3040292 1.68 0.094 -.0866349 1.105138

strat_own | .0015256 .0044572 0.34 0.732 -.0072103 .0102615

strat_own_~m | 1.018902 .3851747 2.65 0.008 .2639733 1.77383

vcpe_own | .0176352 .0057906 3.05 0.002 .0062859 .0289845

vcpe_own_dum | .1093266 .1851291 0.59 0.555 -.2535198 .4721729

bank_own | .0204716 .0160125 1.28 0.201 -.0109122 .0518554

bank_own_dum | .148356 .1961055 0.76 0.449 -.2360037 .5327157

term_prem | -.476271 .2208189 2.16 0.031 .0434739 .909068

eq_premium | -25.70045 14.00727 1.83 0.067 -1.753301 53.15419

libor_rate | -.4063615 .1430768 2.84 0.005 .1259361 .686787

gdp_growth | 2.133895 4.884588 -0.44 0.662 -11.70751 7.439722

time | .3337951 .1431575 2.33 0.020 .0532115 .6143787

time2 | -.0209823 .0113127 -1.85 0.064 -.0431548 .0011902

_cons | -10.41664 1.60505 -6.49 0.000 -13.56248 -7.270802

Table ¹2 - “Summery Statistics Model 1”

. sum event `varlist' time if _sample==1

Variable | Obs Mean Std. Dev. Min Max

event | 9548 .0238793 .1526813 0 1

log_rev | 9548 4.235461 2.7266 -8.1456 12.3575

rev_dum | 9548 .1104943 .3135214 0 1

rd_assets | 9548 .0403188 .1262717 0 2.3188

rd_dum | 9548 .7313574 .4432768 0 1

tbq | 9548 2.079697 2.592172 .0517 32.9312

int_ta | 9548 .1798101 .2188301 0 .9958

tbv_dum | 9548 .1954336 .3965549 0 1

tbv_cap | 9548 .5545999 1.150579 0 19.3581

nppe_ta | 9548 .2569006 .2732383 0 .9985

kce_gp | 9548 .6646253 .3790964 0 1

kce_dum | 9548 .2131336 .4095427 0 1

fcf_ta | 9548 -.0484227 .3388691 -10.4599 11.9316

td_ta | 9548 .2196542 .3255621 0 7.0698

capex_ta | 9548 .0668632 .1161227 0 5.436

cash_ta | 9548 .1938669 .2142386 0 1

sga_rev | 9548 .3534356 .7830254 0 13.6027

sales_dum | 9548 .1501885 .3572748 0 1

f_aquir | 9548 .6367826 1.53054 0 32

no_firms_dum | 9548 .6788856 .4669291 0 1

p_vol | 9548 58.33619 40.63382 2.6313 490.5104

s_ret | 9548 -.0323244 .789275 -1.4482 17.1645

turn | 9548 .0053901 .0084391 0 .2585

inst_own | 9548 33.07558 30.05309 0 100

inst_own_dum | 9548 .1034772 .304597 0 1

insider_own | 9548 13.75574 18.26489 0 100

insider_ow~m | 9548 .1029535 .303914 0 1

strat_own | 9548 34.0428 25.72619 0 100

strat_own_~m | 9548 .0480729 .2139315 0 1

vcpe_own | 9548 6.809592 13.73631 0 98.9

vcpe_own_dum | 9548 .5173858 .4997238 0 1

bank_own | 9548 1.474918 3.358352 0 66.76

bank_own_dum | 9548 .4471093 .4972207 0 1

term_prem | 9548 1.730861 .7414393 -.1058 2.7014

eq_premium | 9548 .0542437 .0072538 .0365 .0643

libor_rate | 9548 1.416093 1.257137 .5831 5.3294

gdp_growth | 9548 .0148504 .0156851 -.0278 .0379

time | 9548 5.401655 2.636464 2 12

Table ¹3 - “Summery Statistics Model 2”

. cloglog event `varlist' time time2

Iteration 0: log likelihood = -885.26867

Iteration 1: log likelihood = -883.84539

Iteration 2: log likelihood = -883.84334

Iteration 3: log likelihood = -883.84334

Complementary log-log regression Number of obs = 9548

Zero outcomes = 9320

Nonzero outcomes = 228

LR chi2(26) = 385.87

Log likelihood = -883.84334 Prob > chi2 = 0.0000

event | Coef. Std. Err. z P>|z| [95% Conf. Interval]

log_rev | -.0145705 .0415033 -0.35 0.726 -.0959156 .0667745

rev_dum | -1.640407 .6503154 -2.52 0.010 -2.915002 -.3658125

int_ta | 1.858785 .3669987 5.06 0.000 1.13948 2.578089

nppe_ta | 1.090053 .4631578 2.35 0.019 .1822808 1.997826

kce_gp | 1.296201 .6216608 2.09 0.037 .0777678 2.514633

kce_dum | .4342987 .5814648 0.75 0.455 -.7053513 1.573949

fcf_ta | .32771 .1627271 2.01 0.044 .0087707 .6466493

capex_ta | -.8387843 1.054983 -0.80 0.427 -2.906514 1.228945

cash_ta | -1.248029 .6440644 -1.94 0.053 -2.510372 .0143137

p_vol | .0025247 .0014819 1.70 0.088 -.0003798 .0054292

no_firms_dum | .3375413 .1572722 2.15 0.032 .0292934 .6457892

s_ret | -1.463935 .1318643 -11.10 0.000 -1.722384 -1.205486

turn | -30.07295 15.664 -1.92 0.055 -60.77382 .6279271

inst_own | .0090697 .0032673 2.78 0.006 .0026659 .0154734

inst_own_dum | .7487919 .2272797 3.29 0.001 .303332 1.194252

insider_own | .0080933 .0048151 1.68 0.093 -.0013442 .0175309

insider_ow~m | .5580197 .2963171 1.88 0.060 -.022751 1.13879

strat_own | .0021895 .0044169 0.50 0.620 -.0064675 .0108466

strat_own_~m | .982941 .3820717 2.57 0.010 .2340941 1.731788

vcpe_own | .0174481 .005764 3.03 0.002 .0061507 .0287454

vcpe_own_dum | .1509174 .1837051 0.82 0.411 -.209138 .5109728

term_prem | -.5274877 .2029336 2.60 0.009 .1297451 .9252302

eq_premium | -27.02054 13.92167 1.94 0.052 -.265425 54.30651

libor_rate | .4238925 .1391919 3.05 0.002 .1510815 .6967036

time | .3172603 .1423692 2.23 0.026 .0382218 .5962987

time2 | -.0203294 .0112971 -1.80 0.072 -.0424713 .0018125

_cons | -10.7587 1.498378 -7.18 0.000 -13.69546 -7.821929

Picture ¹1. “Hazard Rate”

Years After IPO

Picture ¹2. “Hazard Function”

Picture ¹3. “ROC curve for the second year”

Ðàçìåùåíî íà Allbest.ru


Ïîäîáíûå äîêóìåíòû

  • Êàëüêóëÿöèÿ ñòîèìîñòè ïî âèäàì äåÿòåëüíîñòè: êðàòêàÿ õàðàêòåðèñòèêà è îáëàñòü ïðèìåíåíèÿ. Ñóùíîñòü ìåòîäà Activity Based Costing. Èçó÷åíèå ïðîöåññà àíàëèçà îòêëîíåíèé, ñ ïîäðîáíûì ðàññìîòðåíèåì ñîñòàâëÿþùèõ îòêëîíåíèé ïî ïðîèçâîäñòâåííûì ðàñõîäàì.

    êîíòðîëüíàÿ ðàáîòà [200,0 K], äîáàâëåí 05.01.2013

  • Economic essence of off-budget funds, the reasons of their occurrence. Pension and insurance funds. National fund of the Republic of Kazakhstan. The analysis of directions and results of activity of off-budget funds. Off-budget funds of local controls.

    êóðñîâàÿ ðàáîòà [29,4 K], äîáàâëåí 21.10.2013

  • The General Economic Conditions for the Use of Money. Money and Money Substitutes. The Global Money Markets. US Money Market. Money Management. Cash Management for Finance Managers. The activity of financial institutions in the money market involves.

    ðåôåðàò [20,9 K], äîáàâëåí 01.12.2006

  • Cash flow test and balance sheet test. The reasons of not having a single test. The definition and treatment of the debts and liabilities under the both tests. Some differences between Maltese law and UK law in this question.

    ðåôåðàò [10,7 K], äîáàâëåí 11.09.2006

  • Capital Structure Definition. Trade-off theory explanation to determine the capital structure. Common factors having most impact on firm’s capital structure in retail sector. Analysis the influence they have on the listed firm’s debt-equity ratio.

    êóðñîâàÿ ðàáîòà [144,4 K], äîáàâëåí 16.07.2016

  • Òhe balance sheet company's financial condition is divided into 2 kinds: personal and corporate. Each of these species has some characteristics and detail information about the assets, liabilities and provided shareholders' equity of the company.

    ðåôåðàò [409,2 K], äîáàâëåí 25.12.2008

  • Types and functions exchange. Conjuncture of exchange market in theory. The concept of the exchange. Types of Exchanges and Exchange operations. The concept of market conditions, goals, and methods of analysis. Stages of market research product markets.

    êóðñîâàÿ ðàáîòà [43,3 K], äîáàâëåí 08.02.2014

  • Directions of activity of enterprise. The organizational structure of the management. Valuation of fixed and current assets. Analysis of the structure of costs and business income. Proposals to improve the financial and economic situation of the company.

    êóðñîâàÿ ðàáîòà [1,3 M], äîáàâëåí 29.10.2014

  • Research methods are strategies or techniques to conduct a systematic research. To collect primary data four main methods are used: survey, observation, document analysis and experiment. Several problems can arise when using questionnaire. Interviewing.

    ðåôåðàò [16,7 K], äîáàâëåí 18.01.2009

  • The concept and characteristics of the transaction. System of the rules operating social relations in the field of civil movement. Classification of transactions of various types. The validity of the transaction is recognized for it as a legal fact.

    ðåôåðàò [19,5 K], äîáàâëåí 24.03.2009

Ðàáîòû â àðõèâàõ êðàñèâî îôîðìëåíû ñîãëàñíî òðåáîâàíèÿì ÂÓÇîâ è ñîäåðæàò ðèñóíêè, äèàãðàììû, ôîðìóëû è ò.ä.
PPT, PPTX è PDF-ôàéëû ïðåäñòàâëåíû òîëüêî â àðõèâàõ.
Ðåêîìåíäóåì ñêà÷àòü ðàáîòó.