Price discrimination and market power in the international fertiliser market: empirical evidence for exports from Russia

The production capacity of the international fertiliser industry is concentrated and located in few countries. Market structure of the Russian export market for potash fertilizer. Relationships between the estimated parameters and the market situation.

Рубрика Экономика и экономическая теория
Вид статья
Язык английский
Дата добавления 05.05.2022
Размер файла 288,6 K

Отправить свою хорошую работу в базу знаний просто. Используйте форму, расположенную ниже

Студенты, аспиранты, молодые ученые, использующие базу знаний в своей учебе и работе, будут вам очень благодарны.

Размещено на http://www.allbest.ru/

Price discrimination and market power in the international fertiliser market: empirical evidence for exports from Russia

Philipp Goretzki1, Oleksandr Perekhozhuk2, Thomas Glauben2, Jens-Peter Loy3

1Rentenbank, Germany

2Leibniz Institute of Agricultural Development in Transition Economies (IAMO),

Germany

3University of Kiel, Germany

export market fertilizer

Purpose. In 2012, Russia became the world's second-largest exporter increasing its potash exports from 1996 to 2012 more than two times. The top five countries control more than 50 % of the world's exports, particularly 53.4 % (38.0 mln MT) for nitrogen, 73.4 % (3.5 mln MT) for phosphate and 90.8 % (35.5 mln MT) for potash. The objective of this study is to analyse the market structure and market concentration of the Russian export company in the international fertiliser market, and to develop hypotheses about the oligopolistic market behaviour. The empirical part of this study tests the hypotheses by employing econometric models to provide evidence for market power and price discrimination in the international fertiliser market.

Methodology / approach. The empirical analysis in this study relies on the theoretical framework of pricing-to-market (PTM) pioneered by Krugman (1986, 1987). Following Krugman's groundbreaking approach, Knetter (1989) developed an empirical model testing the PTM hypothesis. The major advantages of the Knetter's model are that the pricing behaviour of the export country towards the import countries can be estimated with public statistical data for the export statistics of the export country and bilateral exchange rates between the currencies of the export and import countries.

Results. This study presents empirical evidence for the behaviour of Russian exporters in the international fertiliser market. The estimation results indicate that market power in the export market for nitrogen fertilisers is exercised by Russian exporters in more than two-thirds of the destination countries and in the export market for potash fertilisers in eight out of nine countries. The exercising market power in the export market for potash fertilisers is much more pronounced than in the nitrogen fertiliser export market.

Originality / scientific novelty. Primarily against the background of increased market concentration by the companies in the fertiliser markets and regarding the aforementioned cartel dispute, this study constitutes a first attempt to close the research gap in the empirical literature and to promote empirical research on the market behaviour of export companies in the international markets for nitrogen and potash fertilisers.

Practical value / implications. This study uses econometric techniques to examine the collapse of the potash cartel on the use of price discrimination and the exercising of market power in the international fertiliser market by Russia. The descriptive analysis shows that Russia plays an important role in the export of nitrogen and potash on the world market and many importing destinations. Often Russia in addition to the high market share also has no or few competitors in the various destinations, which supports speculation of exercising market power.

Key words: pricing-to-market (PTM), market power, price discrimination, international market, fertilizer, Russia.

Introduction and review of literature

The international fertiliser market has been growing steadily, up by 1.9 % per year over 2012-2016, and it is estimated to reach 194.1 mln tons by the end of 2016 (FAO, 2016, p. 12). Among other things, this means that the demand for the three nutrients nitrogen, phosphate and potash along with the supply has been growing steadily in recent years. According to predictions of the International Fertilizer Association (IFA), this growth is expected to continue in the future. The demand for nitrogen is going to increase by 1.8 % p.a. between 2011/12 and 2018/19 (IMF, 2015). Global aggregate demand will then reach a historic high. According to the forecast, the demand for potash will grow at the highest rate (2.8 % p.a.) followed by phosphate (1.9 % p.a.) and nitrogen (1.5 % p.a.). The IFA predicts a similar development for the fertiliser supply. Nearly 200 growth projects are planned in the fertiliser industry, slated for implementation in the next five years (Heffer & Prud'homme, 2014: 2 f.). Another 30 projects focus on the extraction of phosphate rock in the mining industry.

The dynamic development of the international fertiliser market is mainly caused by the expansion of global agricultural production. Asia as the largest fertiliser market is the major driving force behind the steady increase in fertiliser consumption. Regions such as Latin America and Africa are contributing to the rising demand as well. Both regions are defined by recovering agriculture and great potential for the expansion of agricultural production. Both regions have the highest growth rates for demand p.a. at 3.7 % and 3.4 % (Heffer & Prud'homme, 2014: 3).

The production capacity of the international fertiliser industry is highly concentrated and located in very few countries. In the countries dominating the market often just a few companies make most of the production and exports. Concentration in the production and trade of potash fertilisers is particularly striking. Essentially there are only two major players worldwide, the potash distribution cartels that jointly control more than 70 % of worlds total potash sales. The Russian/Belarus potash cartel consisting of the Russian “Uralkali” group and the Belarus “Belaruskali” group controls 43 % of worldwide potash fertiliser exports through the Belarus potash distribution company (BKK). The three corporate groups Potash Corp (Canada), Agrium (Canada) and Mosaic (USA) forming the North American Canpotex cartel control 30 % of the world market (Karbalewitsch, 2013). The German fertiliser and salt producer K + S and the Israeli chemical company and fertiliser manufacturer ICL are also significant players in the world market, but they do not belong to any potash cartel. The oligopolistic market structure in the international fertiliser market and the highly concentrated supply suggest the hypothesis market power. This speculation is fuelled by the collapse of the potash cartel in 2013 that kept the prices for potash artificially high before.

In the last few years, numerous agricultural and general economists have undertaken empirical studies analysing imperfect competition, market power and price discrimination in international agricultural and food markets in order to examine the issues of market functioning, pricing and competition with the help of econometric methods and approaches An overview of the extensive literature on the identification and measurement of market power in the international export markets is provided by the studies of Gafarova et al. (2015); Glauben and Loy (2001, 2003); Pall et al. (2014); Pall et al. (2013); Uhl et al. (2016).. The empirical studies are mostly based on econometric model analyses, which have to be viewed in the context of trade theory approaches and assume that international trade is defined by imperfect competition, oligopolistic market structures, cartel agreements and price fixing. The pricing to market (PTM) model has been broadly applied in empirical research to identify market power and oligopolistic behaviour of the exporter through the effects of exchange rate changes between the currencies of the trading partners on export prices with the help of panel data See Glauben and Loy (2003) for a comparison and interpretation of the PTM approach..

Pall et al. (2013) investigate the behaviour of Russian grain exporters based on quarterly data for the period from 2002 to 2010. They find indications of market power in the highly import-dependent countries in North Africa (Lebanon, Pakistan and Syria), the southern Caucasus (Azerbaijan, Armenia, Georgia) and Central Asia (Mongolia). Gafarova et al. (2015) use annual data for the period from 1996 to 2012 to analyse wheat export markets in the KRU countries. They find market power in seven out of 48 Kazakh, in twenty out of 71 Russian and in seventeen out of 65 Ukrainian wheat export markets. Uhl et al. (2016) analyse Russian wheat exports on the basis of annual export data for individual companies, finding empirical evidence of price discrimination behaviour by Russian exporters in 25 out of 61 destination countries in the period from 2002 to 2011.

In addition to numerous descriptive market research studies and market reports See market research studies by Janze et al. (2011, pp. 30-34). indicating a high concentration of the fertiliser industry in the national and international fertiliser markets, there are only a few empirical studies to our knowledge that investigated the market and export structures, market behaviour and pricing in national and international fertiliser markets applying modern econometric approaches and methods. According to a description of the current market situation in the fertiliser industry and the production, consumption, trade and price development trends in view of the high concentration of the industry in international and especially national markets, Hernandez and Torero (2011) examine the effect of market concentration (number of companies, the concentration rate of the four largest companies (CR4) under consideration of the production capacities and the value shares as well as the Herfindahl-Hirschman index (HHI) on the price of urea fertiliser. Using a regression analysis on the basis of the country-specific panel dataset for the period from 1961 through 2002, the authors find on the one hand that fertiliser prices are higher in concentrated markets. On the other hand they find that higher prices in the fertiliser market could also be related to exploiting market power. The causes and sources of market power as well as secret cartel agreements cannot be perfectly explained by the high level of market concentration, since high market concentration is affected by economies of scale in production and the demand for cost efficiency.

Besides rising global demand, shortage of supply there are other factors putting pressure on fertilizer prices included market concentration, cartels and commodity agreements. Because of the rising global demand, market fluctuations, price volatility and higher market concentration in the international fertilizer market, there is an urgent need for econometric analysis, in particular market behaviour and pricing of Russian fertilizer exporters, currently one of the world's biggest fertiliser exporters and players in the export market for nitrogen and potash fertilisers.

The purpose of the article. The objective of this study is to analyse the market structure and market concentration of the Russian export company in the international fertiliser market, and to develop hypotheses about the oligopolistic market behaviour. Furthermore, we test the hypotheses by employing econometric models to provide evidence for market power and price discrimination in the international fertiliser market. The article focuses on Russia because the country was very much in the spotlight of the international public and politics when the potash cartel collapsed. Furthermore, the termination of the cartel by the Russian company Uralkali sent shock waves through the fertiliser industry. The news agencies of the international exchanges reported plunging share prices for the largest potash producers and negative economic projections for the development of fertiliser prices in the international markets.

Primarily against the background of increased market concentration by the companies in the fertiliser markets and regarding the aforementioned cartel dispute, this study constitutes a first attempt to close the research gap in the empirical literature and to promote empirical research on the market behaviour of export companies in the international markets.

Results and discussion. Russia is one of the leading suppliers of nitrogen and potash fertilisers in the world market. Today one-fifth of worldwide nitrogen and potash fertiliser exports come from Russia (COMTRADE, 2015). From 1996 to 2012 Russia accounts for an average share of nearly 20 % of the global nitrogen and potash fertiliser exports. Russia's exports of phosphate fertilisers are of minor importance, its share of world exports is only less than 1 %. Therefore, in this study we focus on the Russian nitrogen and potash fertiliser exports. Table 1 shows that more than half of Russian exports of nitrogen fertilisers are destined to five countries, namely Brazil, China, Mexico, Turkey and USA. The share of Russian exports of the destination market's total imports is very high (above 65 %) for 7 out of 28 destination countries such as China, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Moldavia, Mongolia and Ukraine. In Argentina, Brazil, Finland, Georgia, Honduras, Kyrgyzstan, Morocco, Mexico, Poland and Turkey the share of Russian imports is between 20 and 50 %. The remaining countries (France, India, Italy, Malaysia, Norway, Slovakia, Spain, Hungary, the USA, the UK and Vietnam) show shares of less than 20 % of their imports. The calculations of the Herfindahl-Hirschman index (HHI) Assume that there is an equivalent number of equally sized competitors that supplied nitrogen fertiliser to the countries listed above between 1996 and 2012 in addition to Russia. results for six out of 28 destination countries a highly concentrated market structure The United States Department of Justice (US DOJ) and the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) classify the markets into three types by the size of the HHI: (1) high market concentration (HHI> 0.25), (2) moderate market concentration (0.15 < HHI< 0.25) and (3) low market concentration (HHI < 0.15) (Rogoff, 1996; U.S.DOJ-FTC, 2010).. In fact there is a Russian monopoly in Mongolia according to the HHI (see Table 1).

Table 1

Market structure of the Russian export market for nitrogen fertilisers

in 1996

5-2012

Destinations

Share of Russian exports (%)1

Russian's market share (%)2

Number of competitors3

*4

HHI

Market

concentration

Argentina

1.4

29.1

9

0.11

low

Brazil

18.6

32.3

11

0.09

low

China

4.9

58.5

7

0.14

low

Estonia

0.7

83.2

2

0.50

high

Finland

0.3

46.9

6

0.17

moderate

France

2.5

7.3

8

0.13

low

Georgia

0.0

22.8

6

0.17

moderate

Honduras

1.2

37.3

5

0.20

moderate

India

1.5

5.4

8

0.13

low

Italy

1.1

13.1

10

0.10

low

Kyrgyzstan

0.2

27.3

3

0.33

high

Latvia

1.6

66.0

2

0.50

high

Lithuania

1.5

68.7

4

0.25

moderate

Malaysia

1.2

12.9

7

0.14

low

Morocco

0.9

37.0

6

0.17

moderate

Mexico

6.7

31.2

6

0.17

moderate

Moldovia

0.4

72.7

3

0.33

high

Mongolia

0.2

96.8

1

1.00

high

Norway

0.2

7.6

7

0.14

low

Poland

1.6

30.3

5

0.20

moderate

Slovakia

0.2

13.3

8

0.13

low

Spain

0.5

9.2

11

0.09

low

Turkey

12.3

29.8

9

0.11

low

Ukraine

2.2

92.7

2

0.50

high

Hungary

0.9

14.1

5

0.20

moderate

USA

7.9

7.2

15

0.07

low

United Kingdom

2.4

13.3

8

0.13

low

Vietnam

1.8

5.6

7

0.14

low

Notes. 1 Share of Russian export to destination of total Russian exports. 2 Russian's market share in the total imports of the destination market. 3 A country is considered as a competitor of Russia if its share is >3% in 1996-2012. 4 HHI* ranges from 0 to 1 and was calculated by assuming an equivalent number of equally sized competitors (HHI = 1/n*).

Source: author's own calculations based on COMTRADE database of the UN Statistics Division (COMTRADE, 2015).

We find moderate market concentration for Finland, Georgia, Honduras, Lithuania, Morocco, Mexico, Poland and Hungary. In half the listed countries such as Argentina, Brazil, China, France, India, Italy, Malaysia, Norway, Slovakia, Spain, Turkey, the USA, the UK and Vietnam, Russia faces low market concentrations. Russia's export competitors in these markets and the share of Russian nitrogen exports into these destination countries underscore the dominant market position of the Russian exporters of nitrogen fertilisers in those destination countries.

Potash fertiliser is Russia's leading export product among the industrial minerals. Russia extracted 8.4 mln tons of potash in 2014 Vgl. ROSSTAT (2015: 377).. This puts Russia in second place for global potash production behind Canada with 15.7 mln tons Vgl. CanStat (2016).. In contrast to nitrogen fertilisers, Russian potash fertilisers in the period under review were purchased regularly by only nine countries, as shown in Table 2 by the number of countries listed.

Table 2

Market structure of the Russian export market for potash fertilizer in 1996-2012

Destination

country

Share of Russian exports (%)1)

Russian's market share (%)2)

Number of

competitors 3)

*4

HHI

Market

concentration

Brazil

8.2

16.3

5

0.20

moderate

China

34.3

48.6

6

0.17

moderate

Finland

2.2

45.0

3

0.33

high

India

14.4

24.4

8

0.13

low

Malaysia

3.3

22.1

5

0.20

moderate

Poland

2.2

21.7

3

0.33

high

Ukraine

0.9

11.8

2

0.50

high

Hungary

1.2

72.1

4

0.25

moderate

USA

5.4

4.3

2

0.50

high

Notes. For

footnotes 1}' 3)

and 4) see Table

Source: see Table 1.

From 1996 to 2012 these destinations accounted on average for 72 % of Russian potash fertiliser exports. China and Finland are the most important destinations for Russian potash fertiliser exports. On these import markets Russian exports account for 50 % of total imports. In four of nine destination countries (Brazil, India, Malaysia and Poland) Russia holds a share between 15 and 25 %. Russia's share is less than 15 % in the two remaining countries (Ukraine and the USA). Only in Hungary Russia holds a large share of the potash imports (corresponding to more than 70 %.) But examining the HHI shows that the destination with the highest import ratios, Hungary, exhibits only a moderate market concentration. According to the HHI, the destination countries of China, Finland, Poland, Ukraine and the USA have highly concentrated markets. The HHI is highest for Ukraine and USA (about 50 %).

The data in Table 1 and 2 indicates a high concentration and dominant market position of the Russian exporters in many destination countries. This definitely strengthens Russia's market position in its export markets and can lead to price discrimination and/or the use of market power by Russian exporters in the international markets for nitrogen and potash fertilisers.

Theoretical foundations of the PTM approach. The empirical analysis in this study relies on the theoretical framework of PTM pioneered by Krugman (1986, 1987). Following his groundbreaking research, Knetter (1989) developed an empirical model testing the PTM hypothesis. Assuming that Russian exporters export homogeneous product to N destination markets in which they face downward sloping demand in each destination market і , the market demand curves for Russian exporters is given by:

which indicates the export quantity qit demanded by destination market і in period t. Notice that the export quantity is determined by the export price for a given export product Pjt expressed in the currency of the exporting country (FOB price) in destination country і and period t. eit stands for the bilateral exchange rate with respect to destination country і in period t and is calculated in the importer's currency per unit of the exporter's currency. vit represents a multiplicative demand shifter for destination country і and period t.

The total costs of exporters can be defined by the following cost function:

where Ct denotes a measure of total cost in the exporter's currency summed over all N destination markets, and depends on the export quantities (qit). St includes cost shifters that may shift the cost function in period t, e.g. changes in input prices.

Given this representation of demand functions (1) and cost functions (2), the exporter's profit equation can be written as:

The exporter's supply to destination markets can be derived from the profit maximization framework. Profit maximization with respect to export price dpit charged in each destination market in period t yields a set of first-order conditions:

Recalling that each exporter maximizes profits by setting marginal revenues from sales in each destination market equal to marginal costs in period t, the first- order-conditions for profit maximization can be stated as:

Dividing each term by Pit(dqit/dpit)., equation (5) can be expressed in terms of elasticities:

where MC = dC/dqit is the exporter's common marginal cost and Pit(eitpit) = (dqit/dpit)(pit/qit) is the absolute value of the demand elasticity for imports in each of the destination markets with respect to changes in price. As Krugman (1986, 1987), among others, has showed that the system of equations (6) captures the economic nature of price discrimination and reminds of the classical static monopolist's pricing rule, according to which price markup over marginal cost depends on demand elasticities in the various destination markets.

Gagnon and Knetter (1995) demonstrated that the system of equations (6) can be transformed into a linear relationship by taking the natural logarithm of both sides and using the first-order Taylor series approximation of the function \n (Pit(eitpit)/pit(eitpit) - 1):

where Яi is a destination-specific intercept that captures the constant terms in the Taylor series and Яt is a function of both the level and the elasticity of the demand elasticity:

The ratio of relative change in the exporter's price (d\npit) and the relative change of the exchange rate (d \n eit) depends on the price elasticity of demand in the destination market (ріґ) and its relative change with respect to the price level in the destination market's currency (d \n pit/d \n(eitpit)).

The linear relationship (7) allows for the estimation of model parameters explaining the pricing behaviour of fertiliser exporters across destination countries using a fixed-effects panel regression model of the following form:

where Pit is the Russian fertiliser export price (in logarithm) of destination і in the currency of the export country (FOB price) in the period t. The parameters 6t and Xi represent time and country fixed effects. The parameter Яt is the elasticity of the export price in reference to exchange rate changes. The model variable eit is the bilateral exchange rate measured in units of the importer currency per unit of the exporter currency. uit represents the error term.

A benefit of this approach is that it is easy to obtain public statistical data for the export statistics of the export country with the specification of export quantities and export values to the importing countries; public statistical data about bilateral exchange rates between the currencies of the export and import countries can be used for the empirical analysis. Furthermore, the PTM approach delivers comprehensive results for the econometric study on the basis of panel data that can explain three scenarios for the pricing behaviour of the export country towards the import countries according to Knetter (1989) (see Table 3). In the first market scenario with perfect competition, the export prices are the same for all destinations (prices equal to the marginal costs) since there is no country effect (Aj = 0 ). In such a market form, the bilateral exchange rate is not influenced by the bilateral export prices, which implies (Яi = 0 ) (see Table 3, market situation A). The time effect 6t determines the common marginal costs (and therefore also the price) for all destinations. The second and third market forms include imperfect competition and price discrimination between destinations.

Table 3 Relationships between the estimated parameters and the market situation

Market

situation

Model parameters

Description of the market situation

Ai

Яi

A

Aj = 0

Яi = 0

Perfect competition,

Imperfect competition with ordinary price markup

B

Aj A 0

Яi = 0

Constant demand elasticity ^ constant price markup may differ across destination markets

Aj = 0 / Aj A 0

Яi A0:

Non-constant demand elasticity ^ varying price markup

C1

? ???? < 0

P

Price stabilization in local currency through adjustment of exchange rate effects ^ PTM

C2

? ???? > 0

Increase the effect of the exchange rate

Source: author's own presentation according to Knetter (1993, p. 476), Glauben and Loy (2003), and Pall et al. (2013).

The second market situation assumes constant demand elasticities regarding the respective domestic currency of the destination. Here the marginal costs are the same for all destinations but can vary over time. They are still measured by the time effect et. As given in equation (1), the mark-up is constant but can vary across the destinations, which implies Aj A 0. Now the parameter Aj measures the markup relative to the reference country. The markups are constant percentages. The changes in the bilateral exchange rates do not influence the export prices in different destinations, which means Яt = 0 applies (see Table 3: market situation B).

The third market situation is based on price discrimination with varying demand elasticities. In this market situation, the demand elasticity can vary due to the influence of exchange rate changes. When demand elasticities change, the markup will also change through the marginal costs and the export prices depend on exchange rates. This corresponds with the PTM model of Krugman (1986, 1987), since the optimal markup of a price discriminating monopolist varies between the different destinations and depends on the bilateral exchange rates. In reference to equation (9), this means Aj A 0 and Яt A 0 . Whether the expected leading sign for Яt is negative (positive) depends on whether the demand is less (more) convex than in the demand function with constant elasticities. A negative coefficient Яt is consistent with the original idea of the PTM according to Krugman (1986, 1987) (see Table 3: market situation C1). In contrast, a positive coefficient implies that the exporter increases the effect of the exchange rate (see Table 3: market situation C2).

This discussion could be extended based on Glauben and Loy (2003). It is in particular interesting, whether panel methods could improve the interpretation.

Data and descriptive statistics. The data for the empirical analysis are formed by two panel datasets of Russian nitrogen and potash fertiliser exports. The data covers the period from 1996 to 2012 and contain the average annual exchange rates and export unit values (EUV) on an FOB basis for the respective export goods. The two export goods constitute aggregates at the 4-digit level of the harmonised code (HS) for nitrogen HS-3102 “Mineral or Chemical Nitrogen Fertiliser” and potash HS- 3104 “Mineral or Chemical Potash Fertiliser” Tables A1 and A2 in the appendix to this article show the descriptive statistics for the endogenous and exogenous variables of the individual panel datasets that were compiled for the analysis of Russian fertiliser export markets for nitrogen and potash.. The annual unit values for the two export raw materials being examined were determined from the ratio of the export value (EV) and the export quantity (EQ) for the two export goods: EUV(ij) = EV(ij)/EQ(ij), where i represents the exporting country (Russia) and j the importing destinations. These data were taken from the goods trading statistics of the United Nations (COMTRADE, 2015).

However, the use of unit values or export unit values also has disadvantages. They aggregate data across products for different applications. This assumes that there are no quality differences and that all goods transported to the different destinations are identical (Lavoie & Liu, 2004, p. 2). Knetter (1989) argues that systematic differences in product quality can be accounted for with the help of country dummies. Changes in product qualities that are the same across the countries can be captured the same way with time effects (Lavoie & Liu, 2004, p. 3).

The average annual exchange rates are calculated as the value of a Russian rouble in the currency of the respective destination. Data from the international finance statistics of the International Monetary Fund (IMF, 2015) and Forex trading as well as the foreign exchange services of the OANDA website (OANDA, 2015) are used to calculate the average annual exchange rates. Furthermore, missing exchange rates are obtained from the information of central banks. The OANDA online database lacks the exchange rates for the countries of Georgia, Kyrgyzstan and Moldavia for the years 1996 through 2006 and, for the Ukraine, the exchange rates for the years 1996 and 1997. The missing exchange rates for the countries of Georgia and Kyrgyzstan are calculated indirectly based on the IMF data since the IMF database only offers the exchange rates in US dollars per national currency. For the PTM analysis however, the variable “exchange rate measured in the currency of the import country per currency unit of the export country” is required (here: “national currency per Russian rouble”). Here the variable “US dollar per national (local) currency” was multiplied by the variable (exchange rate) “US dollar per Russian rouble”. The result is the variable “Russian rouble per national (local) currency”. With the inverse value, one obtains the variable required for the PTM analysis. However, the IMF database did not contain the values for the corresponding years for Moldavia. These gaps are filled with data from the Russian and Moldavian central banks. Another problem with using the OANDA online database is that it does not take into account the 1998 currency reform in Russia. Therefore, the exchange rates for the years 1996 and 1997 need to be adjusted by the factor of 1:1,000. The exchange rates for the countries in the Eurozone also required extra treatment: for countries that converted to the Euro in 1998, the exchange rates for the time before the conversion had to be converted to Euros using the officially prescribed exchange rates. Here Finland, France, Italy and Spain are affected. For the Euro countries that adopted the Euro later on (Slovakia - 2008, Estonia - 2010, Latvia - 2013 and Lithuania - 2014), the exchange rates are left in the domestic currency. For Turkey that converted from the “old Turkish lira” to the “new Turkish lira” in 2005, the exchange rates in the currency “new Turkish lira” are used (1,000,000 TRL = 1 TRY).

The countries for the study are selected according to two criteria: for one, those countries importing relatively large quantities of the two goods from Russia and simultaneously buying nitrogen or potash from Russia regularly over the years are selected. Here the datasets in the COMTRADE database are analysed regarding the observations of the trade value. Countries with fewer than 16 observations are excluded. As a result of this analysis, 28 countries are included in this study for Russian nitrogen exports.

Tables A1 and A2 in the appendix show the descriptive statistics of the model variables for the panel dataset used for the econometric analysis of the Russian export market for nitrogen and potash fertilisers. There are relatively large variations in the export unit values (EUV) and nominal exchange rates (NER) between the countries. The EUV ranges from 1.922 roubles (Vietnam) to 5.160 roubles (Mongolia) for nitrogen. The variation coefficient of the exchange rates ranges from 0.702 (Georgia) to 0.953 % (France). The nominal exchange rates (NER) range from 0.032 roubles (Latvia) to 820.392 roubles (Vietnam). Here the variation coefficient ranges from 0.249 (Moldavia) to 1.114 % (Lithuania). For potash fertiliser, the EUV ranges from 4.293 roubles (India) to 8.153 roubles (Ukraine). Here the variation coefficient has a range from 0.845 (China) to 1.459 % (Ukraine). The nominal exchange rates (NER) range from 0.045 roubles (Finland) to 11.555 roubles (Hungary). The variation coefficient ranges from 0.255 (Ukraine) to 0.955 % (USA).

Estimation results of the panel model analysis. The econometric model analysis of Russian fertiliser export markets for nitrogen and potash fertilisers is conducted in the statistics program STATA (version 13) with the application of several estimation methods (STATA, 2015, pp. 446-481). Initially the least squares dummy variable estimator (LSDV estimator) with dummy variables for cross-section and time series effects with robust standard errors is used. Then the PTM model is estimated as a linear regression with a panel-corrected standard error and application of the panel-specific AR1 autocorrelation structure. Finally, an econometric estimation of the PTM model is performed using the fixed effect model (FE), a panel model with country-specific and time-specific fixed effects. The estimated coefficients of the PTM models are robust and nearly identical, regardless of the estimation method. Tables 4 and 5 show the estimation results for the PTM models using the fixed effect estimates for nitrogen and potash fertilisers.

While the same number of periods is available for the analysis of both export markets (t = 17), the number of destinations differs. There are 28 destination countries for the nitrogen fertiliser market and 9 destination countries for the potash fertiliser market. The descriptive statistics of the panel data used and the number of observations indicate that an unbalanced panel is being used for the analysis of the nitrogen fertiliser market. The analysis of the nitrogen fertiliser market is based on a balanced panel. The number of observations is 474 and 153 accordingly. The determination coefficient of 0.608 for the nitrogen market and 0.511 for the potash fertiliser market exhibits a good fit for the estimated PTM models.

While nearly half at 26 of 56 estimated PTM parameters for the nitrogen fertiliser market are statistically significant with a 10 % significance level, more than two-thirds of the estimated PTM parameters for the potash fertiliser market are statistically significant at the 10 % significance level. As expected, the estimated parameters for the country price effect and the exchange rate elasticity coincide with the theoretical model result. Comparing the results of this study with the results obtained by Pall et al. (2013) and Gafarova et al. (2015) for the Russian wheat export market shows that the estimated parameters are very similar.

Export market for nitrogen fertiliser. A central result of this study is the insight that there is imperfect competition in the Russian export market for nitrogen fertiliser in two-thirds of the destination countries that are studied (17 out of 28 countries). There is imperfect competition due to different markups in Finland, Georgia, Hungary, Mongolia, Moldavia, Norway and Vietnam. The demand elasticity varies and the effect of the exchange rate is significantly different from zero (Яt Ф 0). Russian nitrogen exports stabilise the price in the domestic currency by adjusting the exchange rates in Mexico and Norway (Яt < 0) and intensify the effect of exchange rate changes in Finland, Georgia, Hungary, Mongolia and Vietnam (Яt > 0) (see Table 4, market situation C1 and C2).

Countries in which PTM is proven and where Russia also has few competitors and/or a high market share are Moldavia with two competitors and 72.7 % market share. but especially Mongolia with no competitors and 96.8 % market share and Ukraine with one competitor and 92.8 % market share (see Table 1). In addition the transportation costs are low due to geographical conditions. The adjustment of the mark-up induced by the bilateral exchange rate changes depends on the elasticity of the residual demand. If this is less convex a constant elasticity is set. Then Russian nitrogen exports stabilise the price in the domestic currency (negative exchange rate effect). This is the case in Mexico and Norway. On the other hand, the price in the domestic currency increases when the residual demand becomes inelastic. Then Russian nitrogen exports stabilise the prices in the domestic currency. These results do not harmonise with possible explanations for price stabilisation in the local currency determined by Knetter (1989: 207-208).

Table 4

Results ol

¦ the PTM model for nitrogen export

Destinations

А,-

t-Statistic

Яi

t-Statistic

Market situation

Argentina

-

-

0.160

[ 1.67]

A

Brazil

0.246

[ 0.95]

0.198**

1 2.561

C2

China

0.030

[ 0.12]

0.290***

1 5.121

C2

Estonia

-0.291

[-1.34]

0.048

[ 0.75]

A

Finland

0.624**

1 2.751

0.239***

1 4.101

C2

France

-0.246

[-1.15]

0.035

[ 0.39]

A

Georgia

1.187**

1 2.421

0.525***

1 4.091

C2

Honduras

-0.227

[-1.11]

0.089

[ 0.45]

A

Hungary

-0.924***

1-3.021

0.193***

1 4.531

C2

India

-0.431

[-1.49]

0.314***

1 3.401

C2

Italy

-0.372

[-1.40]

-0.048

[-1.32]

A

Kyrgyzstan

-0.477

[-1.58]

0.577*

1 1.781

C2

Latvia

0.146

[ 0.65]

0.117***

1 3.071

C2

Lithuania

-0.199

[-1.02]

0.102**

1 2.561

C2

Malaysia

-0.136

[-0.58]

0.193***

1 3.831

C2

Mexico

-0.242

[-1.09]

-0.122*

1-1.811

C1

Moldova

0.485**

1 2.521

0.970***

1 9.101

C2

Mongolia

-1.375***

1-2.991

0.364***

1 4.641

C2

Morocco

-0.198

[-0.92]

0.179***

1 2.981

C2

Norway

-1.111***

1-4.401

-0.577***

1-3.531

C1

Poland

-0.156

[-0.63]

0.059

[ 0.77]

A

Slovakia

-0.294

[-1.17]

0.033

[ 0.92]

A

Spain

-0.375

[-1.49]

-0.038

[-0.40]

A

Turkey

-0.345

[-1.28]

0.086

[ 1.47]

A

Ukraine

-1.754*

[-1.86]

-0.769

[-1.68]

B

United

Kingdom

-0.327

[-1.61]

-0.039

[-0.86]

A

USA

0.006

[ 0.02]

0.114***

13.661

C2

Vietnam

-5.596***

[-5.05]

0.718***

15.101

C2

Constant

1.270***

[ 5.18]

-

-

Observations

474

Groups

17

R2-squared

0.608

R2: within

0.608

R2: adjusted

0.556

R2: overall

0.001

AIC

-280.509

R2: between

0.623

Notes. The reference country is Argentina. Star symbols ***, ** and * represent the significance levels of 1%, 5% and 10%.

Source: author's own estimation.

The market size in both Mexico and Norway is relatively small. Firstly, share of Russian export to destination of total Russian exports correspond to 6.7 and 0.2 % respectively. Secondly, Russian's market share in the total imports of the destination market accounts for 31.2 % in Mexican and 7.6 % in Norwegian markets (see Table 1). A further explanation regarding the number of competitors or competing companies does not confirm the hypothesis. The number of competing countries is relatively small: six for Mexico and seven for Norway (see Table 1).

The estimated parameters of the PTM model for the Russian export market for nitrogen fertilisers indicate that there is a competitive market or perfect competition in only one-third of the destination countries (Estonia, France, Honduras, Italy, Poland, Slovakia, Spain, Turkey and the UK). Here both the price-specific country effect and the effect of the exchange rate are not statistically significant (see Table 3, market situation A). One can assume that the residual demand for Russian nitrogen is elastic and the behaviour is competitive. Another possibility is that Russia has market power but the countries are too well integrated into the world market and arbitrage is possible. This would balance out any price difference so that Russia would not engage in any price discrimination. The law of one price applies in these countries. Russia therefore applies the same markup for these countries. All of the countries exhibiting no indications of price discrimination in the results are well integrated into the world market. With the exception of Slovakia, all of them are coastal states. This means that Russia has many (potential) competitors in these destinations and/or accounts for only a small proportion of the total nitrogen imports. Here Estonia is an exception. With a market share of 83.2 % Russia dominates the Estonian fertiliser market and is the leading supplier there (see Table 1). It is therefore likely that the residual demand for Russian nitrogen is elastic and the behaviour is competitive.

Only for the Ukraine the estimation results indicate the second market situation B with constant demand elasticity with a constant markup (see Table 3). This is indicated by the price effect, which is significantly different from zero and the exchange rate effect that is not significantly different from zero. It is important to note that a statistically significant price effect does not necessarily indicate imperfect competition. since the price effect can also capture constant quality differences here (Falk & Falk, 2000; Knetter, 1989). See the discussion in Glauben and Loy (2003) on the impact of exchange rates on costs.

Export market for potash fertiliser. In contrast to Russian nitrogen exports, eight out of nine countries exhibit an imperfect competitive market with the application of different markups. The analysis finds PTM in four countries - China, Hungary, Malaysia and India. Each of them exhibits imperfect competition with different markups. Following the theory, there are different demand elasticities. In all countries, where PTM is found, Russian potash exports stabilise the price in the local currency (Яi < 0) (see Table 5, market situation C1).

The analysis of Russian potash exports in the period from 1996 to 2012 shows that only Ukraine exhibits a competitive market out of the countries that are studied (see Table 5, market situation A). PTM is not found in any of the countries where the price effect is not significant. Otherwise, Russia would apply a markup in those countries when this compensates for the effect of exchange rate changes, since the export price should always be higher than the marginal costs. This indicates that

Russia applies a common market on the marginal costs (see Table 3, market situation B).

Table 5

Results of the PTM model for potash export

Destinations

At

t-Statistic

Яi

t-Statistic

Market situation

Brazil

-

-

-1.254*

[-2.06]

C1

China

2.369*

[ 2.08]

-0.670*

[-1.93]

C1

Finland

0.676

1 1.601

-0.717*

[-1.83]

C1

Hungary

4.970*

[ 1.93]

-0.868*

[-1.78]

C1

Indian

3.442*

[ 1.88]

-0.858*

[-1.77]

C1

Malaysia

1.335*

[ 2.01]

-0.848*

[-1.78]

C1

Poland

1.197

1 1.621

-0.935**

[-2.21]

C1

Ukraine

5.659

1 1.701

1.471

1 1.141

A

USA

0.659

1 1.651

-0.761*

[-1.92]

C1

Constant

-1.254*

[-2.06]

-

-

Observations

153

Groups

17

R-squared

0.511

R2: within

0.511

R2: adjusted

0.449

R2: overall

0.658

AIC

87.612

R2: between

0.787

Notes. The reference country is Argentina. Star symbols significance levels of 1%, 5% and 10%.

** and * represent the

Source: author's own estimation.

Russia does not have a dominant market position for potash in any of the countries that are under study here (see Table 2). Only in Hungary with a Russian market share of 72.1 % could such a market scenario be conceivable. Russia has three competitors for this destination. Hungary is also well integrated into the world market.

The results of the PTM model of the Russian potash export market are defined to a great extent by the negative estimated parameters for the elasticity of the export price in reference to exchange rate changes. One can establish the hypothesis that price stabilisation in the local currency can be due to price fixing and cartel agreements by the Russian exporters in the export market for potash fertilisers. These agreements have to be assigned to the international market shares.

Conclusions

The results of this study indicate speculation around the collapse of the potash cartel on the use of price discrimination and the exercising of market power in the international fertiliser market by Russia. The descriptive analysis shows that Russia plays an important role in the export of nitrogen and potash on the world market and many importing destinations. Not only the consistently large export quantities are striking, but also the partly high market share in the overall international market and in various importing countries. Often Russia in addition to the high market share also has no or few competitors in the various destinations, which supports speculation of exercising market power.

The empirical model estimates for the nitrogen fertiliser market show that there is evidence of PTM behaviour by the Russian fertiliser exporters in 7 out of 28 destination countries. Out of these countries, Russia has few competitors and/or a high market share only in Moldavia, Mongolia and the Ukraine. The econometric estimation results for the potash fertiliser market indicate price discrimination behaviour of the Russian potash fertiliser exports for 8 out of 9 destination countries. However, Russia does not have a significantly large market share and/or few competitors here. Hungary could be an exception here. A sufficiently perfect market is found in only one of 9 countries under study.

The empirical results for the analysis of the behaviour of Russian exporters in the international markets for nitrogen and potash fertilisers can be summarised as follows: One, based on price fixing and cartel agreements, the hypotheses regarding price discrimination behaviour by the Russian exporters in the export markets can be tested empirically using the pricing-to-market approach. The interpretation of the estimated parameters of the model is economically plausible and corresponds to the stated hypotheses. Two, the estimation results indicate that market power in the export market for nitrogen fertilisers is exercised by Russian exporters in more than two-thirds of the destination countries and in the export market for potash fertilisers in eight out of nine countries. Three, exercising market power in the export market for potash fertilisers is much more pronounced than in the nitrogen fertiliser export market.

References

CanStat. Canadian fertilizer production. by product type and fertilizer year. cumulative data annual (metric tonnes). CANSIM.

COMTRADE (2015), United Nations Comtrade Database - International Trade Statistics, available at: http://comtrade.un.org.

Fahlbusch, M. (2009), Preisfindung auf den internationalen Mдrkten fьr Milcherzeugnisse - Ein Vergleich von Ansдtzen zur Analyse von Marktmacht. Georg-August-Universitдt Gцttingen, Gцttingen, Germany.

Falk, M. and Falk, R. (2000), Pricing to Market of German Exporters: Evidence from Panel Data. Empirica, vol. 27(1), pp. 21-46.

Food and agriculture organization of the united nations (2016), Current world fertilizer trends and outlook to 2016, available at: http://www.fao.org/tempref/AG/agp/docs/cwfto16.pdf.

Gafarova, G., Perekhozhuk, O. and Glauben, T. (2015), Price discrimination and pricing-to-market behavior of Black Sea region wheat exporters. Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics, vol. 47(3), pp. 287-316. https://doi.org/10.1017/aae.2015.16.

Goretzki, P., Perekhozhuk, O., Glauben, T. and Loy, J.-P. (2017), Market Power in the International Fertiliser Market: Empirical Evidence for Exports from Russia. XV EAAE Congress “Towards Sustainable Agri-Food Systems: Balancing between Markets and Society”. European Association of Agricultural Economists (EAAE), Parma, Italy.

Glauben, T. and Loy, J.-P. (2001), Marktmacht ausgewдhlter Branchen der deutschen Ernдhrungswirtschaft auf internationalen Mдrkten. German Journal of Agricultural Economics, vol. 2(8), pp. 100-108.

Glauben, T. and Loy, J.-P. (2003), Pricing-to-Market versus Residual Demand Elasticity Analysis of Imperfect Competition in Food Exports: Evidence from Germany. Journal of Agricultural & Food Industrial Organization, vol. 1, pp. 1 -19.

Heffer, P. and Prud'homme, M. (2014), Fertilizer Outlook 2014-2018. Paper presented at the 82nd IFA Annual Conference. Sydney. Australia.

Hernandez, M. A. and Torero, M. (2011), Fertilizer Market Situation: Market Structure, Consumption and Trade Patterns, and Pricing Behavior. Markets, Trade, and Institutions Division. International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI). Washington. USA.

International Monetary Fund (2015), available at: www.imf.org.

Janze, C., Schmidt, C. and Theuvsen, L. (2011), Der Exportmarkt fьr Dьngemittel. In E. Young ed. Agribusiness in Deutschland Exportmдrkte im Fokus.

Karbalewitsch, W. (2013), Der Kali-Krieg zwischen Belarus und Russland. Belarus-Analysen, nr. 14, pp. 4-21.

Knetter, M. M. (1989), Price discrimination by U.S. and German exporters. The American Economic Review, vol. 79(1), pp. 198-210.

Knetter, M. M. (1993), International Comparisons of Pricing-to-Market Behavior. The American Economic Review, vol. 83(3), pp. 473-489.

Krugman, P. (1986), Pricing to Market When the Exchange Rate Changes. NBER Working Paper No. 1926. Cambridge, UK. https://doi.org/10.3386/w1926.

Krugman, P. (1987), Pricing-to-Market When the Exchange Rate Changes. Real Financial Linkages Among Open Economies. MIT Press, Cambridge, UK.

Lavoie, N. and Liu, Q. (2007), Pricing-to-Market: Price Discrimination or Product Differentiation? American Journal of Agricultural Economics, vol. 89, no. 3, pp. 571-581.

OANDA (2015), Historical Currency Converter - Trade Currency Online, available at: www.oanda.com.

Pall, Z., Perekhozhuk, O., Glauben, T., Prehn, S. and Teuber, R. (2014), Residual demand measures of market power of Russian wheat exporters. Agricultural Economics, vol. 45(3), pp. 381-391. https://doi.org/10.1111/agec.12072.

Pall, Z., Perekhozhuk, O., Teuber, R. and Glauben, T. (2013), Are Russian Wheat Exporters Able to Price Discriminate? Empirical Evidence from the Last Decade. Journal of Agricultural Economics, vol. 64(1), pp. 177-196. https://doi.org/10.1111/1477-9552.12006.

Rogoff, K. (1996), The Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle? Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 34(2), pp. 647-668.

ROSSTAT (2015), Russian Statistical Yearbook. Moskau: Fцderaler Dienst fьr staatliche Statistik der Russischen Fцderation.

STATA (2015), Longitudinal-Data/Panel-Data Reference Manual: Release 14. College Station. TX: StataCorp LP.

U.S.DOJ-FTC (2010), Horizontal Merger Guidelines, available at: https://www.ftc.gov/sites/default/files/attachments/merger-review/100819hmg.pdf.

Uhl, K., Perekhozhuk, O. and Glauben, T. (2016), Price Discrimination in Russian Wheat Exports: Evidence from Firm-level Data. Journal of Agricultural Economics, vol. 67(3), pp. 722-740. https://doi.org/10.1111/1477-9552.12118.

Appendix Table A 1

Summary statistics of export unit values and exchange rates on nitrogen data set (HS-3102)

Destinations

N

Export unit values (EUV)

Nominal exchange rate (N

4ER)

MEAN

MIN

MAX

CV

MEAN

MIN

MAX

CV

Argentina

17

3.711

0.452

10.990

0.893

0.114

0.034

0.200

0.417

Brazil

17

4.080

0.497

10.005

0.763

0.095

0.057

0.200

0.473

China

16

3.398

0.665

8.071

0.735

0.470

0.203

1.600

0.955

Estonia

17

3.994

0.484

11.186

0.860

0.765

0.355

2.400

0.892

Finland

17

4.137


Подобные документы

  • Law of demand and law of Supply. Elasticity of supply and demand. Models of market and its impact on productivity. Kinds of market competition, methods of regulation of market. Indirect method of market regulation, tax, the governmental price control.

    реферат [8,7 K], добавлен 25.11.2009

  • The stock market and economic growth: theoretical and analytical questions. Analysis of the mechanism of the financial market on the efficient allocation of resources in the economy and to define the specific role of stock market prices in the process.

    дипломная работа [5,3 M], добавлен 07.07.2013

  • Assessment of the rate of unemployment in capitalist (the USA, Germany, England, France, Japan) and backward countries (Russia, Turkey, Pakistan, Afghanistan). Influence of corruption, merges of business and bureaucracy on progress of market economy.

    реферат [15,5 K], добавлен 12.04.2012

  • Natural gas market overview: volume, value, segmentation. Supply and demand Factors of natural gas. Internal rivalry & competitors' overview. Outlook of the EU's energy demand from 2007 to 2030. Drivers of supplier power in the EU natural gas market.

    курсовая работа [2,0 M], добавлен 10.11.2013

  • Economic entity, the conditions of formation and functioning of the labor market as a system of social relations, the hiring and use of workers in the field of social production. Study of employment and unemployment in the labor market in Ukraine.

    реферат [20,3 K], добавлен 09.05.2011

  • Issues about housing prices formation process. Analytical model of housing prices. Definition a type of relationship between the set of independent variables and housing prices. The graph of real housing prices of all Russian regions during the period.

    курсовая работа [1,6 M], добавлен 23.09.2016

  • Transition of the Chinese labor market. Breaking the Iron Rice Bowl. Consequences for a Labor Force in transition. Labor market reform. Post-Wage Grid Wage determination, government control. Marketization Process. Evaluating China’s industrial relations.

    курсовая работа [567,5 K], добавлен 24.12.2012

  • Financial bubble - a phenomenon on the financial market, when the assessments of people exceed the fair price. The description of key figures of financial bubble. Methods of predicting the emergence of financial bubbles, their use in different situations.

    реферат [90,0 K], добавлен 14.02.2016

  • Mergers and acquisitions: definitions, history and types of the deals. Previous studies of post-merger performance and announcement returns and Russian M&A market. Analysis of factors driving abnormal announcement returns and the effect of 2014 events.

    дипломная работа [7,0 M], добавлен 02.11.2015

  • A theoretic analysis of market’s main rules. Simple Supply and Demand curves. Demand curve shifts, supply curve shifts. The problem of the ratio between supply and demand. Subsidy as a way to solve it. Effects of being away from the Equilibrium Point.

    курсовая работа [56,3 K], добавлен 31.07.2013

Работы в архивах красиво оформлены согласно требованиям ВУЗов и содержат рисунки, диаграммы, формулы и т.д.
PPT, PPTX и PDF-файлы представлены только в архивах.
Рекомендуем скачать работу.