Capital structure choice in the emerging markets
How do firms choose their capital structure and which factors affect their decision. The reason for the inclusion is that diversified macroeconomic conditions and institutional quality enable me to analyze their relevance for the capital structure.
Рубрика | Экономика и экономическая теория |
Вид | автореферат |
Язык | английский |
Дата добавления | 15.09.2018 |
Размер файла | 151,2 K |
Отправить свою хорошую работу в базу знаний просто. Используйте форму, расположенную ниже
Студенты, аспиранты, молодые ученые, использующие базу знаний в своей учебе и работе, будут вам очень благодарны.
(2)
Based on the significance and interpretations of these interactive variables we can test the following hypotheses:
H4.1: Profitable firms in case of economic growth prefer less debt in their capital structure
H4.2: Larger firms with increasing grow opportunities prefer more debt in their capital structure
H4.3: Firms with higher tangible assets ratio prefer more debt in their capital structure in less corruptive environment
The model is estimated with the Fixed-Effects estimation, which is equivalent to the (1) Least Squares Dummy Variables specification of the model. This model is applicable as there is an unobserved heterogeneity in each firm's capital structure due to missing variables. As all the macroeconomic and institutional variables vary with time, this allows us to estimate their effects.
4. Data description and statistics
The sample consists of total 1,763 non-financial and non-utility firms from capital IQ from 6 developing countries for a period from 2007 to 2014. The countries are Chile, Egypt, Malaysia, Poland, Thailand, and Turkey. The number of firms for each country are 122, 110, 461, 310, 488, and 272 in the respective order. All the firms employ IFRS accounting standard. There are missing values for some year-firm observations. So, there are 11,041 efficient observations. The number of efficient firm-year observations for each country are 797, 563, 3 139, 2 013, 3 056, and 1 745 in the respective order. The Macro Institutional data is attached for each year firm observation Macroeconomic variables are obtained from World Bank Development Indicators. The institutional variables are obtained from World Bank Doing Business and Transparency international. The individual firm data was winsorized at 1% and 99% levels to remove the effects of outliers.
The Table 1 summarize the statistics of variables:
Variable |
Obs |
Mean |
Std. Dev. |
Min |
Max |
|
MTLev |
11,319 |
0.2937379 |
0.2876095 |
0 |
1.286304 |
|
BTLev |
12,992 |
0.2103779 |
0.180943 |
0 |
.7333333 |
|
MLLev |
11,317 |
0.1130315 |
0.1610905 |
0 |
.7767981 |
|
BLLev |
12,992 |
0.0835095 |
0.1140437 |
0 |
.5183946 |
|
Profit |
12,252 |
5.52804 |
5.052042 |
0.083 |
28 |
|
Size |
12,992 |
4.585169 |
1.72826 |
0.4762342 |
9.23436 |
|
Tang |
12,992 |
0.5046488 |
0.2300677 |
0.0293905 |
.973913 |
|
Growth |
11,313 |
1.161898 |
1.328569 |
0.0845982 |
9.056157 |
|
GDP |
14,104 |
4.057995 |
3.174948 |
-4.704466 |
11.1135 |
|
Inf |
14,104 |
4.139174 |
3.995665 |
-5.015799 |
19.49526 |
|
Cred |
14,104 |
73.96645 |
19.49914 |
18.75 |
100 |
|
Tax |
14,104 |
73.34452 |
11.11622 |
39.24 |
86.6 |
|
Corrupt |
14,104 |
45.17069 |
10.57378 |
28 |
73 |
Table 1, Source: Own calculations
The Table 2 on the next page shows the correlations matrix between all dependent and independent variables. As expected, there is a high correlation within all different definitions of leverage. For the explanatory variables the highest correlations are between profit and growth (41.4%), credit quality and corruption (35.5%), credit quality and inflation (35.1%), GDP and Inflation (33.6%). Other correlations are quite small, so there should be no problem of multicollinearity.
MTLev |
BTLev |
MLLev |
BLLev |
Profit-1 |
Size-1 |
Tang-1 |
Growth-1 |
GDP |
Inf |
Cred |
Tax |
Corrupt |
||
MTLev |
1.0000 |
|||||||||||||
BTLev |
0.7173 |
1.0000 |
||||||||||||
MLLev |
0.6672 |
0.5349 |
1.0000 |
|||||||||||
BLLev |
0.4462 |
0.6617 |
0.8179 |
1.0000 |
||||||||||
Profit-1 |
-0.2957 |
-0.1727 |
-0.2162 |
-0.1189 |
1.0000 |
|||||||||
Size-1 |
0.2071 |
0.2593 |
0.3128 |
0.3729 |
-0.0919 |
1.0000 |
||||||||
Tang-1 |
-0.4582 |
-0.5596 |
-0.3352 |
-0.3879 |
0.1047 |
-0.2991 |
1.0000 |
|||||||
Growth-1 |
-0.2676 |
-0.0340 |
-0.1671 |
-0.0066 |
0.4139 |
-0.1150 |
0.0367 |
1.0000 |
||||||
GDP |
0.0446 |
-0.0106 |
0.0293 |
-0.0033 |
-0.0347 |
0.0238 |
0.0247 |
0.0194 |
1.0000 |
|||||
Inf |
0.0181 |
0.0074 |
-0.0067 |
-0.0131 |
-0.0151 |
0.0757 |
0.0136 |
-0.0297 |
0.3356 |
1.0000 |
||||
Cred |
0.0760 |
-0.1005 |
0.0525 |
-0.0457 |
-0.0203 |
-0.0989 |
0.0350 |
-0.1165 |
0.0093 |
-0.3506 |
1.0000 |
|||
Tax |
0.0473 |
0.0344 |
0.0497 |
0.0519 |
-0.0413 |
0.0862 |
0.0694 |
0.0023 |
0.1241 |
-0.1947 |
0.2112 |
1.0000 |
||
Corrupt |
0.0929 |
-0.0407 |
0.1465 |
0.0796 |
-0.0661 |
0.0880 |
-0.0889 |
-0.0422 |
0.0610 |
-0.1296 |
0.3548 |
0.1753 |
1.0000 |
Table 2. The Correlations Matrix, source: Own calculations
5. Regression Analysis Results
BTLev |
MTLev |
||||||
Coef. |
Std. Err. |
P>t |
Coef. |
Std. Err. |
P>t |
||
Profit-1 |
-0.0013475*** |
0.0003987 |
0.001 |
-0.002505*** |
0.0006979 |
0.000 |
|
Size-1 |
0.0366356*** |
0.005541 |
0.000 |
0.0837358*** |
0.0103664 |
0.000 |
|
Tang-1 |
-0.1967558*** |
0.018445 |
0.000 |
-0.2821428*** |
0.0285306 |
0.000 |
|
Growth-1 |
0.0014742 |
0.0019444 |
0.448 |
-0.0133122*** |
0.0033892 |
0.000 |
|
GDP |
-0.0005805* |
0.0003363 |
0.084 |
0.001987*** |
0.000637 |
0.002 |
|
Inf |
0.0006934** |
0.000322 |
0.031 |
0.0017084** |
0.0007507 |
0.023 |
|
Cred |
-0.0002318 |
0.0003331 |
0.487 |
0.0039575*** |
0.0006792 |
0.000 |
|
Tax |
-0.0005246 |
0.0003329 |
0.115 |
-0.0017691** |
0.0007856 |
0.024 |
|
Corrupt |
0.0001958 |
0.0003327 |
0.556 |
0.0042827*** |
0.0007468 |
0.000 |
|
R2 overall |
0.2326 |
0.1455 |
|||||
N total |
9,289 |
9,071 |
|||||
F-statistic |
25.90 |
0.000 |
51.42 |
0.000 |
Table 3. Model (1) Estimations on Total Leverage, Source: Own calculations
BLLev |
MLLev |
||||||
Coef. |
Std. Err. |
P>t |
Coef. |
Std. Err. |
P>t |
||
Profit-1 |
-0.0005518* |
0.0002953 |
0.062 |
-0.0014096*** |
0.0004165 |
0.001 |
|
Size-1 |
0.0188202*** |
0.0040427 |
0.000 |
0.0377914*** |
0.0055931 |
0.000 |
|
Tang-1 |
-0.0905884*** |
0.0115197 |
0.000 |
-0.1232144*** |
0.0165055 |
0.000 |
|
Growth-1 |
0.0034216** |
0.0014799 |
0.021 |
-0.0020715 |
0.0018548 |
0.264 |
|
GDP |
-0.0001097 |
0.0002862 |
0.702 |
0.0008991 |
0.0003952 |
0.023 |
|
Inf |
-0.0000155 |
0.0002475 |
0.950 |
-0.0002527 |
0.0004222 |
0.550 |
|
Cred |
-0.0003351 |
0.0002508 |
0.182 |
0.0017798*** |
0.0004246 |
0.000 |
|
Tax |
-0.0000601 |
0.000237 |
0.800 |
-0.0012521 |
0.0004489 |
0.005 |
|
Corrupt |
0.0000139 |
0.000241 |
0.954 |
0.0015187*** |
0.0004244 |
0.000 |
|
R2 overall |
0.2164 |
0.1605 |
|||||
N total |
9,289 |
9,071 |
|||||
F-statistic |
13.02 |
0.000 |
27.43 |
0.000 |
Table 4. Model (1) Estimations on Long Term Leverage, Source: Own calculations
The tables above report the model estimation results for all definitions of leverage. The standard errors reported are robust to heteroskedasticity, as the Modified Wald test for groupwise heteroskedasticity detected it. Overall, the book definitions of leverage show less significant correlations especially with macroeconomic and institutional variables than market value definitions.
Regarding the first hypothesis: the conventional firm factors seem to have a significant impact on firm's leverage. The F-test for a group significance of variables indicate p-value close to 0 for every definition of leverage. The most consistent factors are size and tangibility, which are significant at 1% level for every definition of leverage. What is surprising, tangibility has a negative impact on the leverage, and this is different from the evidence from the developed markets. This is consistent with San Martin and Saona (2017), who also report negative relationship between tangibility and leverage. Size has a positive sign for every estimate, as expected. The profitability has a consistent negative sign and it is significant at 1% for every definition of leverage, except for BLLev, for which it is significant at 10%. Growth is significant at 1% level for MTLev with a negative sign, and it is also significant at 5% level for BLLev. Overall, we do not reject the first hypothesis.
GDP is significant only at 1% level in MTLev and has a positive sign. For book total leverage it is significant at 10% and has a negative sign. So, the hypothesis is rejected for every definition of leverage, except for a BLLev. Overall, this finding is inconsistent and further work is required in this direction.
Inflation is significant at 5% level for BTLev and MTLev with a positive sign. So, we do not reject our hypothesis for those definitions of leverage, while reject for the effect on long term leverages.
Only market definitions of leverage are significantly affected by quality of institutions. Better anticorruption environment and better quality of credit institutions show the positive relationship with MTLev and MLLev and are significant at 1%. The institutional quality of tax system seems to be significant at 5% only for MTLev and has an expected negative sign. Overall, the test of group significance gives positive result for institutional variables at any reasonable significance levels for market definitions of leverage. So, we may conclude that H3.1 and H3.3 are not rejected for MTLev and MLLev, while H3.2 is not rejected for MTLev.
6. Interactive variables analysis
BTLev |
MTLev |
||||||
Coef. |
Std. Err. |
P>t |
Coef. |
Std. Err. |
P>t |
||
Profit-1 |
-0.0015357*** |
0.0004784 |
0.001 |
-0.0010091 |
0.0008208 |
0.219 |
|
Size-1 |
0.0362636*** |
0.0055212 |
0.000 |
0.0963598*** |
0.0106528 |
0.000 |
|
Tang-1 |
-0.3507816*** |
0.0386051 |
0.000 |
-0.384254*** |
0.0609759 |
0.000 |
|
Growth-1 |
-0.0005479 |
0.004815 |
0.909 |
0.0076534 |
0.0051644 |
0.139 |
|
GDP |
-0.000218 |
0.0003491 |
0.532 |
0.0019123*** |
0.0006491 |
0.003 |
|
Inf |
0.0009407*** |
0.0003377 |
0.005 |
0.0020357*** |
0.0007679 |
0.008 |
|
Cred |
-0.0000963 |
0.0003284 |
0.769 |
0.0038587*** |
0.0006737 |
0.000 |
|
Tax |
-0.000629* |
0.0003346 |
0.060 |
-0.0021244*** |
0.0007911 |
0.007 |
|
Corrupt |
-0.0007311** |
0.0003533 |
0.039 |
0.0038317*** |
0.0007843 |
0.000 |
|
GDP-1*Profit-1 |
0.0000618 |
0.0000394 |
0.117 |
-0.0002911*** |
0.0000691 |
0.000 |
|
Size-1*Growth-1 |
0.0006334 |
0.0010881 |
0.561 |
-0.0056821*** |
0.001308 |
0.000 |
|
Tang-1* Corrupt-1 |
0.0033849*** |
0.0007939 |
0.000 |
0.0024296** |
0.0012261 |
0.048 |
|
R2 overall |
0.2289 |
0.1445 |
|||||
N total |
9,289 |
9,071 |
|||||
F-statistic |
24.08 |
0.000 |
40.58 |
0.000 |
Table 5. Model (2) Estimations on Total Leverage, Source: Own calculations
BLLev |
MLLev |
||||||
Coef. |
Std. Err. |
P>t |
Coef. |
Std. Err. |
P>t |
||
Profit-1 |
-0.000394 |
0.0003456 |
0.254 |
-0.0006599 |
0.0004997 |
0.187 |
|
Size-1 |
0.0202064*** |
0.0041888 |
0.000 |
0.0447695*** |
0.0059282 |
0.000 |
|
Tang-1 |
-0.190982*** |
0.0268475 |
0.000 |
-0.2155403*** |
0.0366336 |
0.000 |
|
Growth-1 |
0.0045797** |
0.0022288 |
0.040 |
0.0094224*** |
0.0027926 |
0.001 |
|
GDP |
0.0000701 |
0.0002994 |
0.815 |
0.0009475** |
0.0004087 |
0.021 |
|
Inf |
0.0001695 |
0.0002539 |
0.504 |
-0.0000137 |
0.0004331 |
0.975 |
|
Cred |
-0.0002713 |
0.0002459 |
0.270 |
0.0017551*** |
0.0004202 |
0.000 |
|
Tax |
-0.0001873 |
0.0002384 |
0.432 |
-0.0014615*** |
0.0004539 |
0.001 |
|
Corrupt |
-0.0005581** |
0.0002649 |
0.035 |
0.0010513** |
0.0004482 |
0.019 |
|
GDP-1*Profit-1 |
-0.0000184 |
0.0000297 |
0.535 |
-0.0001391*** |
0.000038 |
0.000 |
|
Size-1*Growth-1 |
-0.0002842 |
0.0005806 |
0.625 |
-0.0030892*** |
0.0007372 |
0.000 |
|
Tang-1* Corrupt-1 |
0.0022288*** |
0.0004983 |
0.000 |
0.0021337*** |
0.0007199 |
0.003 |
|
R2 overall |
0.2571 |
0.1628 |
|||||
N total |
9,289 |
9,071 |
|||||
F-statistic |
11.14 |
0.000 |
23.32 |
0.000 |
Table 6. Model (2) Estimations on Long-Term Leverage, Source: Own calculations
*, **, *** denotes the level of significance of 10%; 5% and 1% respectively.
The addition of interactive variables does not change the model in a serious way, but signs of some coefficients change. What is interesting, interactive variable affected the significance of corruption for the book definitions of leverage, making it significant at 5% level for BTLev and BLLev. For MTLev profitability and growth became insignificant.
To explore the effect of interactive variables, I will calculate the coefficients of one variable at the different percentiles of another variable. The analysis is done for all the significant interactive variables.
First, I start with , which significant for all models
Percentile |
0,05 |
0,25 |
0,5 |
0,75 |
0,95 |
|
Corrupt |
32 |
35 |
44 |
51 |
70 |
|
Tang-1 |
0,123967 |
0,334799 |
0,501401 |
0,680473 |
0,886442 |
|
BTLev |
||||||
Tang-1+Tang-1*Corrupt-1 |
-0,24246 |
-0,23231 |
-0,20185 |
-0,17815 |
-0,11384 |
|
Corrupt+Corrupt-1*Tang-1 |
-0,00031 |
0,000402 |
0,000966 |
0,001572 |
0,002269 |
|
Tang-1 old |
-0,19676 |
|||||
Corrupt Old |
0,000196 |
|||||
MTLev |
||||||
Tang-1+Tang-1*Corrupt-1 |
-0,30651 |
-0,29922 |
-0,27735 |
-0,26034 |
-0,21418 |
|
Corrupt+Corrupt*Tang-1 |
0,004133 |
0,004645 |
0,00505 |
0,005485 |
0,005985 |
|
Tang-1 old |
-0.2821428 |
|||||
Corrupt Old |
0,004283 |
|||||
BLLev |
||||||
Tang+Tang*Corrupt |
-0,11966 |
-0,11297 |
-0,09291 |
-0,07731 |
-0,03497 |
|
Corrupt+Corrupt*Tang |
-0,00028 |
0,000188 |
0,000559 |
0,000959 |
0,001418 |
|
Tang-1 old |
-0.0905884 |
|||||
Corrupt Old |
0,0000139 |
|||||
MLLev |
||||||
Tang-1+Tang-1*Corrupt-1 |
-0,14726 |
-0,14086 |
-0,12166 |
-0,10672 |
-0,06618 |
|
Corrupt+Corrupt-1*Tang-1 |
0,001316 |
0,001766 |
0,002121 |
0,002503 |
0,002943 |
|
Tang-1 old |
-0,12321 |
|||||
Corrupt Old |
0,001519 |
Table 7. Interactive variable analysis for tangibility and corruption, Source: Own calculations
It seems that higher corruption perception index interactive variable consistently overcomes the older estimate of tangibility on leverage starting from 75th percentile of corruption perception index. While the tangibility starting from 25th percentile reinforces the positive effect of corruption on leverage. So, overall, the hypothesis H4.3 is confirmed to be true.
Next, the similar table for interactive variable
Percentile |
0.05 |
0.25 |
0.5 |
0.75 |
0.95 |
|
Size-1 |
1.976855 |
3.399528 |
4.454347 |
5.671604 |
7.68708 |
|
Growth-1 |
0.234978 |
0.515264 |
0.788252 |
1.254711 |
3.422493 |
|
MTLev |
||||||
Size-1+Size-1*Growth-1 |
0.095025 |
0.093432 |
0.091881 |
0.08923 |
0.076913 |
|
Growth-1+Size-1*Growth-1 |
-0.003579 |
-0.011663 |
-0.017656 |
-0.024573 |
-0.036025 |
|
Size-1 old |
0.083736 |
|||||
Growth-1 Old |
-0.01331 |
|||||
MLLev |
||||||
Size-1+Size-1*Growth-1 |
0.044044 |
0.043178 |
0.042334 |
0.040893 |
0.034197 |
|
Growth-1+Size-1*Growth-1 |
0.003315 |
-0.00108 |
-0.00434 |
-0.0081 |
-0.01432 |
|
Size-1 old |
0.037791 |
|||||
Growth-1 Old |
-0.00207 |
Table 8. Interactive variable analysis for size and growth, Source: Own calculations
It seems like the effect of the interactive variable on size overcomes the older estimate only at 95th percentile of growth. While for growth opportunities the interactive effect of size magnifies the estimate since 50th percentile. Thus, the hypothesis H4.2 is rejected because the direction of effect is inverse from expected. Finally, we inspect the table for interactive variable . I will consider only effect of GDP on profitability, as it the inverse relationship does not make sense.
Percentile |
0,05 |
0,25 |
0,5 |
0,75 |
0,95 |
|
GDP |
-2,52583 |
1,725668 |
4,693723 |
6,006722 |
9,427665 |
|
MTLev |
||||||
Profit-1+GDP-1*Profit-1 |
-0,00027 |
-0,00151 |
-0,00238 |
-0,00276 |
-0,00375 |
|
Profit-1 Old |
-0,00251 |
|||||
MLLev |
||||||
Profit-1+GDP-1*Profit-1 |
-0,00031 |
-0,0009 |
-0,00131 |
-0,0015 |
-0,00197 |
|
Profit-1 Old |
-0,00141 |
Table 9. Interactive variable analysis for GDP growth and profitability, Source: Own calculations
The effect of interactive GDP variable reinforces the negative effect of profitability consistently since 75th percentile. This suggests that during economic growth firms might repay their debt more actively, and this lowers the leverage. Thus, the hypothesis H4.1 is not rejected.
Conclusion
This paper contributes to existing research on capital structure in developing markets. The evidence suggests that based on a sample containing 1,736 firms for a period 2007-2014 from 6 countries with emerging economies, the conventional capital factors seem to capture some capital structure decisions. The included countries are Chile, Egypt, Malaysia, Poland, Thailand, and Turkey. The significance and signs of profitability, size, and growth coincide with the evidence from developed countries, while tangibility is negatively significant.
Inflation with GDP are positively significant at explaining the market values of total and long-term leverages. The effects of better credit institutional quality and better anticorruption environment are significantly positively related to market value of total and long-term leverages, while the negative significant effect of better tax system institutional quality is captured only at total market leverage.
The interesting part of the work is the analysis of interactive variables. The results are that profitable firms have less leverage during the expansion of economy, the negative impact of tangibility is less pronounced in the better anticorruption environment, and firms with high growth opportunities prefer less leverage with increase in size.
List of references
Arellano, M., Bond, S., 1991. Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Rev. Econ.Stud. 58 (2), 277-297.
Baker, K. H., Martin, (2011), Capital Structure and Corporate Financing Decisions: Theory, Evidence, and Practice, Print ISBN:9780470569528
Baker, M., Wurgler, J., 2002. Market timing and capital structure. Journal of Finance 57, 1-32.
Blundell, R., and S. Bond. Initial Conditions and Moment Restrictions in Dynamic Panel Data Models. Journal of Econometrics, 87 (1998), 115-143.
Bokpin, G. A., (2009), Macroeconomic development and capital structure decisions of firms: Evidence from emerging market economies. Studies in Economics and Finance, 26(2), 129-142
Booth, L., V. Aivazian, A. Demirgь?-Kunt, and V. Maksimovic. (2001) Capital structures in developing countries. Journal of Finance 56 87-130.
Chakraborty, Indrani, (2010), Capital structure in an emerging stock market: The case of India. Research in International Business and Finance, 24(3), 295-314
Danis, A., Rettl, D.A., Whited, T.M., (2014), Refinancing, profitability, and capital structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 114, 424-443
Djankov, S., Ganser, T., McLiesh, C., Ramalho, R., and Shleifer, A. (2010). The Effect of Corporate Taxes on Investment and Entrepreneurship. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2 (3): 31-64.
Djankov, S., McLiesh, C., and Shleifer., A. (2007). Private Credit in 129 Countries. Journal of Financial Economics 12 (2): 77-99.
Donaldson, G. (1961). Corporate debt capacity: A study of corporate debt policy and the determination of corporate debt capacity. Boston: Division of Research, Harvard School of Business Administration
Drobetz, W. and Wanzenried, G., (2006), What determines the speed of adjustment to the target capital structure? Applied Financial Economics, 16(13), 941-958
Espinosa M., C., Maquieira V., C., Vieito, J., & Gonzбlez A., M. (2012). Capital Structures in Developing Countries: The Latin American case. Investigaciуn Econуmica, 71(282), 35-54.
Fama, E.F., French, K.R., 2002. Testing trade-off and pecking order predictions about dividend and debt. Review of Financial Studies, 15, 1-33.
Fan, J., S. Titman, and G. Twite. An international comparison of capital structures and debt maturity choices.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 47 (2012): 23-56.
Fischer, E. O., Heinkel, R. and Zechner, J. (1989), Dynamic Capital Structure Choice: Theory and Tests. The Journal of Finance, 44: 19-40.
Fischer, E., R. Heinkel, and J. Zechner. “Dynamic capital structure choice: Theory and Tests.” Journal of Finance 44 (1989): 19-40.
Frank, M., Goyal, V.K., 2003. Testing the pecking order theory of capital structure. J. Financial Econ. 67, 217-248.
Frank, M.Z., Goyal, V.K., 2009. Capital structure decisions: which factors are reliably important? Financ. Manage. 38, 1-37.
Ghosh, S., 2007. Bank debt use and firm size: indian evidence. Small Bus. Econ. 29, 15-23.
Graham, J.R., Harvey, C.R., 2001. The theory and practice of corporate finance: evidence from the field. J. Financial Econ. 60, 187-243.
Graham, J.R., Leary, M.T., 2011. A review of empirical capital structure research and directions for the future. Ann. Rev. Financial Econ. 3, 309-345.
Graham, John R. and Harvey, Campbell, (2001), The theory and practice of corporate finance: evidence from the field, Journal of Financial Economics, 60, issue 2-3, p. 187-243
Hang, M., et al. (2017), Measurement matters--A meta-study of the determinants of corporate capital structure. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance
Haugen, R. A. and Senbet, L. W. (1978), The Insignificance of Bankruptcy Costs To The Theory of Optimal Capital Structure. The Journal of Finance, 33: 383-393.
Jensen, M.C., 1986. Agency cost of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. American Economic Review 72, 323-329.
Jensen, M.C., Meckling, W.H., 1976. Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs, and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3, 305-360
Kayhan, A. and Titman, S., (2007), Firms' histories and their capital structures, Journal of Financial Economics, 83, issue 1, p. 1-32
Kraus, A. and Litzenberger, R. H. (1973), A State?Preference Model of optimal financial leverage. The Journal of Finance, 28: 911-922
Kumar, S., Colombage, S., Rao, P., (2017), Research on capital structure determinants: a review and future directions, International Journal of Managerial Finance, 13(2), 106-132
La Porta, R.; F. Lopez-de-Silanes; A. Shleifer; and R. W. Vishny. “Law and Finance.” Journal of Political Economy, 106 (1998), 1113-1155.
Leary, M. T. and Roberts, M. R. (2005), Do Firms Rebalance Their Capital Structures? The Journal of Finance, 60: 2575-2619.
Leland, H. E. (1994), Corporate Debt Value, Bond Covenants, and Optimal Capital Structure. The Journal of Finance, 49: 1213-1252.
Marsh, P. (1982), The Choice Between Equity and Debt: An Empirical Study. The Journal of Finance, 37: 121-144.
Miller, M.H. (1977) Debt and Taxes, Journal of Finance, 32(2), 261-275.
Modigliani, F., Miller, M., 1958. The cost of capital: corporation finance and the theory of investment. Am. Econ. Rev. 48, 261-297.
Modigliani, F., Miller, M., 1963. Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital: a correction. Am. Econ. Rev. 53, 433-443.
Myers, S. C. (1977) Determinants of Corporate Borrowing. Journal of Financial Economics, 5, 147-175.
Myers, S.C. and Majluf, N.S. (1984) Corporate Financing and Investment Decisions When Firms Have Information That Investors Do Not Have, Journal of Financial Economics, 13, 187-221.
Myers, S.C., (1984). Capital structure puzzle. Journal of Finance 39, 575-593.
Цztekin, Ц., (2015), Capital Structure Decisions around the World: Which Factors Are Reliably Important?, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 50(03), 301-323
Цztekin, Ц., and M. J. Flannery. (2012) Institutional Determinants of Capital Structure Adjustment Speeds. Journal of Financial Economics, 103, 88-112.
Rajan, R.G. and Zingales, L. (1995) What Do We Know about Capital Structure? Some Evidence from International Data, Journal of Finance, 50(5), 1421-60.
Ross, S. (1977). The Determination of Financial Structure: The Incentive-Signalling Approach. The Bell Journal of Economics,8(1), 23-40.
San Martнn, Pablo and Saona, Paolo, (2017), Capital structure in the Chilean corporate sector: Revisiting the stylized facts, Research in International Business and Finance, 40C, 163-174
Servaes, H. and Tufano, P. (2006), The Theory and Practice of Corporate Capital Structure, http://faculty.london.edu/hservaes/Corporate%20Capital%20Structure%20-%20Full%20Paper.pdf
Shyam-Sunder, L., Myers, S.C., (1999). Testing static tradeoff against pecking order models of capital structure. Journal of Financial Economics 51, 219-244.
Strebulaev, I. (2007) Do tests of capital structure theory mean what they say? Journal of Finance, 62, 1747-1787.
Titman, S., Wessels, R., 1988. The determinants of capital structure choices. Journal of Finance 43, 1-19.
Toy, N., Stonehill, A., Remmers, L., Wright, R. and Beekhuisen, T. (1974) A Comparative International Study of Growth, Profitability and Risk as Determinants of Corporate Debt Ratios in the Manufacturing Sector, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 875-886.
Xuan Vinh Vo, Determinants of capital structure in emerging markets: Evidence from Vietnam, Research in International Business and Finance, 40, 2017, 105-113
S&P Capital IQ https://www.capitaliq.com/
The World Bank Development Indicators http://databank.worldbank.org/data/source/world-development-indicators#
The World Bank Doing Business, http://www.doingbusiness.org/Custom-Query
Transparency International, https://www.transparency.org/research/cpi/overview
Размещено на Allbest.ru
Подобные документы
The Human Capital Theory. External Migration in Kazakhstan. The major causes of out-migration in Germany. Migration in Kazakhstan during 2004-2010. Internal Migration in Kazakhstan. The major factors determining the nature of the migration to Russia.
реферат [2,2 M], добавлен 14.04.2012Gas pipeline construction: calculating the pipe diameter, the pressure required for the transportation of natural gas compressors. The definition of capital costs for construction and operation of the pipeline. Financial management of the project.
статья [774,7 K], добавлен 05.12.2012Формирование корпоративных структур. Порядок государственного регулирования деятельности. Мировая практика деятельности холдингов. Финансовые показатели, управление, органы управления, факторы роста, управление рисками в АО "System Capital Management".
реферат [179,4 K], добавлен 24.01.2014Directions of activity of enterprise. The organizational structure of the management. Valuation of fixed and current assets. Analysis of the structure of costs and business income. Proposals to improve the financial and economic situation of the company.
курсовая работа [1,3 M], добавлен 29.10.2014Priority for the importance of Economy of Ukraine. Sources, functions, structure of income Household as a politico-economic category. Family income - the economic basis of reproduction. Levels of income of the population. The structure of family income.
реферат [22,5 K], добавлен 28.10.2011База для распространенной практики пассивного инвестирования. Формирование и поддержание диверсифицированного портфеля ценных бумаг. Оценка ставок доходности. Расчет ценовой модели акционерного капитала при помощи САРМ (Capital Assets Pricing Model).
презентация [257,8 K], добавлен 15.10.2011Organizational structure of "Samruk-Kazyna" JSC. Formation of financial resources of the Fund. Mining and power assets directorate. The characteristic stages of the process of registration of new legal entities. Cash flow from the operating activity has.
отчет по практике [2,6 M], добавлен 02.02.2015Investments as an economic category, and their role in the development of macro- and microeconomics. Classification of investments and their structure. Investment activity and policy in Kazakhstan: trends and priorities. Foreign investment by industry.
курсовая работа [38,8 K], добавлен 05.05.2014General characteristic of the LLC DTEK Zuevskaya TPP and its main function. The history of appearance and development of the company. Characteristics of the organizational management structure. Analysis of financial and economic performance indicators.
отчет по практике [4,2 M], добавлен 22.05.2015Project background and rationales. Development methodology, schedule planning. Company mission and vision. Organization of staff and company structure. Procurement system target market. Implementation of procurement system. Testing, user manual.
дипломная работа [6,8 M], добавлен 28.11.2013